Difference between revisions of "Proposal"
Adam Hardy (talk | contribs) m (→The Framework) |
Adam Hardy (talk | contribs) m |
||
(14 intermediate revisions by the same user not shown) | |||
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
− | == |
+ | == The Case for Change== |
+ | Climate science provides the quantity of CO<sub>2</sub> emissions allowable under various emissions scenarios. The dramatic crossroads for humanity as outlined by the United Nations Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change's 2022 report offers two ways forward: without concerted, rapid and unprecedented efforts to reduce CO<sub>2</sub> emissions, the effects of climate change will likely cause massive loss of life, property, and nature. Doing nothing but rely on technological developments to bring about the obsolescence of fossil fuels is a policy that forecasting scenarios show cannot keep global warming below 3.0°C. This will bring global economic recessions along with damage and adaptation costs in the order of trillions of US dollars. This may induce governments to shut down the fossil fuel industry in short order to limit further losses, regardless of the drastic, disorganised impact on the economy. |
||
+ | The Paris Agreement was passed unanimously. That in itself was a feat of international diplomacy. However the Nationally Determined Contributions are not enforceable<ref>ECIU 2019: '''The Paris Agreement''' |
||
− | Rationing of supply is a well-known but little discussed policy. In the case of rationing of fossil fuel products (carbon), it brings about the direct reduction of the supply of fossil fuels and hence the reduction of associated CO<sub>2</sub> emissions. The policy put forward here uses this guarantee of emissions reduction and the greater chance of achieving emissions reduction targets. It is an advantage over any other kind of carbon pricing policies, such as carbon taxes, industrial emissions trading schemes or other means of controlling fossil fuel demand. What CO<sub>2</sub> emissions are allowable for different climate targets is a known quantity. Setting this quantity per capita and issuing that to citizens could be a lot more effective than trying to guess the “right” price for carbon, especially in the time-constrained bounds of a radical and robust response to climate change called for by the United Nations. We summarise the arguments and cite the discussion and evidence below. |
||
+ | ([https://eciu.net/briefings/international-perspectives/the-paris-climate-agreement Energy & Climate Intelligence Unit Briefings])</ref>. The 1.5°C limit to global warming imagined in the agreement is looking increasingly unachievable. The Climate Action Tracker<ref>Climate Action Tracker, 2019: '''USA Pledges and Targets critically insufficient''' ([https://climateactiontracker.org/countries/usa/pledges-and-targets Climate Action Tracker])</ref> currently shows most monitored countries have not made sufficient commitments in their NDCs to be compatible with the agreement. |
||
+ | == The Policy Concept== |
||
− | The Universal Carbon Credits as a Carbon Currency framework (UCCs) is also known as Total Carbon Rationing. In the current public narrative, carbon rationing is seen as draconian and carbon taxes, regulation and subsidies have for many years been favoured more. We describe how UCCs on the contrary could be the most effective approach in the short timeframe available for the Paris 1.5°C target, with the lowest risk of failure, a significant measure of popularity and the greatest fairness, locally, nationally and globally. |
||
+ | https://ecocore.org/wp-content/uploads/CarbonCurrencySystem04.png |
||
− | == |
+ | === Government === |
+ | The UK Committee on Climate Change produced an extensive and wide-ranging document<ref name=":0">UK Committee on Climate Change: ''Net Zero 2050 Strategy'' [https://www.theccc.org.uk/publication/net-zero-the-uks-contribution-to-stopping-global-warming/ UKCCC] (2019)</ref> outlining a policy path to achieve net zero CO<sub>2</sub> emissions by 2050 and immediately realised 2 problems: were their recommendations plausible<ref name=":1">UK Parliament Commons Select Committee 2019: '''Government’s target for ‘net-zero’ by 2050 undeliverable unless clean growth policies introduced''' ([https://www.parliament.uk/business/committees/committees-a-z/commons-select/science-and-technology-committee/news-parliament-2017/clean-growth-report-published-17-19/ UK Parliament])</ref> and are they even the best choice?<ref name=":2">Workman, M. et al: ''Decision making in contexts of deep uncertainty - An alternative approach for long-term climate policy'' [https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S1462901119304319 Science Direct] (2019)</ref> |
||
− | In this framework, the carbon allocation would be paid regularly to citizens via a digital carbon account much like a Universal Basic Income. Children and teenagers would receive a percentage of the adult quota. Governments would withhold a certain percentage of citizens' UCCs like a tax, to pay the carbon costs of running public services. |
||
+ | Already academic policy analysts predict that governments will be unable to rise to the challenge without fundamental organisational restructuring<ref>UK Government: ''UK Government’s target for ‘net-zero’ by 2050 undeliverable unless clean growth policies introduced.'' [https://committees.parliament.uk/committee/135/science-and-technology-committee/news/101056/governments-target-for-netzero-by-2050-undeliverable-unless-clean-growth-policies-introduced/ UK Government Science and Technology Committee] 2020</ref>. This policy would allow decision-makers to focus on how much carbon emissions to allow, rather than how to implement those emissions cuts. |
||
− | To reduce CO<sub>2</sub> emissions to zero under such a framework, the first rationing period would begin by allocating enough UCCs to cover society’s existing emissions, so at an individual level it would only impact those with an above-average carbon footprint. The allocation would then be steadily reduced over time. Reduction might need to be stepped up in circumstances of accelerating climatic instability, or allocations might temporarily increase to stave off exceptional economic damage, as with any policy, but always with the additional guarantee that due to supply restrictions essential reduction targets will be met. |
||
+ | === Individuals === |
||
− | UCCs fulfil the basic rationing mechanism via a change in the point at which the UCCs are collected and controlled. Traditionally, retail businesses would collect rations (e.g. in war-time) for controlled products for audit by the relevant government authority. |
||
+ | The concept of a carbon allowance is similar to rationing, which is categorised by economists as a fundamentally progressive fiscal policy - in other words, it is fair. Studies looking at rationing in the 1940s and 1950s show this. The quantity of carbon tokens in the allowance should be allocated on a per capita basis to citizens. |
||
+ | In this system, the carbon allowance would be paid regularly via a personal carbon account. Children and teenagers would receive a percentage of the adult quota. Governments would withhold a certain percentage of citizens' allowance like a tax, to pay the carbon costs of running public services. |
||
− | Under the UCC framework, retail businesses would charge customers carbon credits, as well as money, for all products and services, but the businesses do not then surrender those credits to the carbon authority – instead, they use their UCC income to pay for the goods and services they use in their supply chain. This method of charging credits and paying them goes on back through the supply chain until the end source is reached, with the carbon providers (oil/gas/coal extraction companies). |
||
+ | To reduce CO<sub>2</sub> emissions to zero, the first allowance period would begin by allocating enough carbon tokens to cover society’s existing emissions. At the individual level, this would only impact those with an above-average carbon footprint. The allocation would then be steadily reduced over time. Reduction might need to be stepped up in circumstances of accelerating climatic instability, or the allowance might temporarily increase to stave off exceptional economic damage, but always with the additional guarantee that due to supply restrictions, reduction targets will be met. |
||
− | At source, the carbon providers would charge UCCs on their fossil fuel sales, weight for weight in tonnes, kilos and grams of carbon. Their accounts would be subject to audit by a central authority. All carbon extracted – gas, oil, coal – would be monitored and the oil companies would surrender the incoming UCCs to the carbon authority at the end of each rationing period. |
||
+ | To prevent anybody being unfairly affected by the system, the government would hold back a percentage of everybody’s carbon allowance. This can be used to supplement those in extra need of carbon tokens through no fault of their own. |
||
− | == The Effects == |
||
− | Such a scheme would immediately push businesses to seek out the lowest emission options in their supply chain. This is not dissimilar to a carbon tax, but the price signal here would be far more obvious, not masked by other non-carbon costs. The ability to purchase extra UCCs on the open market from citizens or businesses would minimise problems when adaptation is slow or insufficient for whatever reason. |
||
+ | If introduced, every citizen and every business would have to become adept at handling their carbon tokens in the same way as money. it allows individual citizens to make their own decisions on where to make savings. Few of us would be forced to cut down in all areas of consumption, most could make carbon savings where convenient for our lifestyle. No one would be imposing decisions on our behalf. |
||
− | The broad reach of the UCC framework means faster, cheaper and more efficient outcomes than any government carbon taxes, emissions trading scheme or pricing policy, because it would cover traditionally excluded business sectors like aviation, shipping, inbuilt or imported emissions, public services or the military. |
||
+ | === Business === |
||
− | For the public too, per-capita allocation of UCCs as opposed to a tax would be seen to be fair, in particular at the start when the carbon allocation should be high enough for all but the most profligate carbon users to adopt without hardship. A carbon tax is inherently unfair due to its burden falling disproportionately on those with lower incomes, but UCCs would be allocated equally per capita, and allow those on low incomes who have on average smaller carbon footprints to profit from selling their excess. |
||
+ | Business ultimately plays by a set of rules defined in law and is typically only concerned only with profit and loss generated by its actions within that context. For business, UCC is relatively basic. It makes going green part of the rules. |
||
+ | Under the system, businesses would charge customers carbon tokens, as well as money, for all products and services, which it would carefully manage to cover all of its own carbon expenditure. |
||
− | The UCC framework would also be democratically more popular than targeted CO<sub>2</sub> emissions reduction measures (frequent flyer tax, meat production controls, vehicle fuel duties) because it allows individual citizens to make their own decisions on where to make savings. Few of us would be forced to cut down in all areas of consumption, most could make carbon savings where convenient for our lifestyle. No one would be imposing decisions on our behalf. |
||
+ | Every product or service that is bought and sold would be subject to the system: every vendor, every merchant, every shopkeeper, every business person who sells anything must put the carbon price on their product or service next to the cash price, even if it is truly a zero emissions product. It provides a practical solution for difficult industry sectors like aviation, shipping, inbuilt or imported emissions, public services or the military. |
||
− | As well as the doubts surrounding carbon tax, there are also major issues with purely legislative or statutory policies and whether it is even within the fundamental organisational abilities of current democratic power structures to design, legislate for and implement the huge range of regulations that would be required for deep decarbonisation of the economy by any other means than the UCC framework in the timescale available. |
||
+ | The businesses use their carbon token income to pay for the goods and services they use in their supply chain. This method of pricing the carbon in everything in the supply chain goes back through the supply chain until the end source is reached, with the carbon producers (the oil/gas/coal extraction companies). |
||
− | == Feasibility == |
||
− | One significant advantage of UCCs is the continual dynamic update of the UCC price charged for each product or service as business becomes more carbon-neutral. The price tag would display exactly how much CO<sub>2</sub> in total was generated in the manufacture and supply of the product. It would be reduced by the vendors to reflect environmental improvements as they take place. This real-time ‘green flag’ lends a dynamism to the decarbonisation process on a scale impossible to achieve by any bureaucratic mandates or carbon tax scheme. |
||
+ | Carbon tokens would flow via every business transaction through the supply chain from the end-carbon-consumer (citizen) to the original carbon producer. So they would flow through the economy as a second parallel currency, affecting every product or service which exists and is for sale, from televisions to train tickets, and requiring two figures on the price tag – a price in local currency ($, £, €, ¥ etc) and a carbon price in tokens. |
||
− | The UCC mechanism would at the same time facilitate and promote negative emissions – natural solutions, carbon sequestration – by providing UCCs as payment from the central carbon authority that administers the framework, neatly circumventing the contentious issue of ‘who pays?’ for the carbon drawdown measures. |
||
+ | From the technological perspective, business would be compelled to introduce accounting software to account for carbon token income and expenditure. Key to the system and how it generates the carbon price for products and services is the rule that businesses, commerce and industry do not receive any carbon tokens as an allowance: the citizens create the market for the products and services, and their willingness or not to pay any given carbon price is the ultimate feedback in the process. |
||
− | The roll-out could be implemented by central banks using digital currency frameworks – unilaterally by nation or within trading blocs by the creation of carbon borders with non-UCC trading partners, where customs authorities act as proxy and impose the UCC price on the importers at the border. It could also be negotiated multilaterally with agreements on national UCC allocations via the existing UNFCCC-compliant GCI Contraction and Convergence treaty model. |
||
+ | With modern supply chains, a product or service’s carbon price is kept up to date by the businesses involved, from manufacture right through packaging, freight, and storage. The final carbon price to the end consumer is simply the accumulation of carbon token costs that were added on and demanded in payment at each step in the supply chain. This establishes a direct link between the volume of carbon tokens allocated by the central carbon authority and the final CO<sub>2</sub> emissions produced in the economy in any one period. |
||
− | Locally, the UCC framework offers every one of us a transparent, simple path to act on climate within a demonstrably fair system. Nationally, the framework allows governments a transparent, simple flexibility in implementing decarbonisation policy according to their political principles. Internationally, UCCs under the GCI Contraction and Convergence system could become the tool of choice as other policies likely continue to prove ineffective. Nations seeking robust collaboration on climate measures – in the light of worryingly slow progress – would do well to turn their Nationally Determined Contributions into Negotiated Contributions, to adopt the UCC framework and control of fossil fuel supply with willing partners in order to achieve the goals of the 2015 Paris Agreement. |
||
+ | One significant advantage of carbon tokens is the continual dynamic update of the UCC price charged for each product or service as business becomes more carbon-neutral. The price tag would display exactly how much CO<sub>2</sub> in total was generated in the manufacture and supply of the product. It would be reduced by the vendors to reflect environmental improvements as they take place. This real-time ‘green flag’ lends a dynamism to the decarbonisation process on a scale impossible to achieve by any bureaucratic mandates or carbon tax scheme. |
||
− | == Social and Economic Advantages of UCCs as a Carbon Currency == |
||
+ | Such a scheme would immediately push businesses to seek out the lowest emission options in their supply chain, so that their offerings have the lowest carbon price they can manage and the best chances against the competition. Products or services which currently sell at a high price due to their low CO<sub>2</sub> emissions, high sustainability or eco-friendliness will become much more attractive due to their low carbon price. |
||
− | # Maximise sustainable rate of CO<sub>2</sub> emissions reduction |
||
− | #: Universal Carbon Credits will act as an economic tuning mechanism allowing the rate of CO<sub>2</sub> emissions reduction to be balanced against any negative impacts it causes. The goal should be to keep reduction rates at the highest economically feasible level. Faced with, e.g. deteriorating climatic conditions, sea level changes, or unexpected synergies appearing with the growth of the low carbon economy, carbon rationing gives a straightforward lever to soft-pedal or step up decarbonisation |
||
− | # Direct control over fossil fuel supply |
||
− | #: The supply of Universal Carbon Credits allocated to citizens would be decided for each period in the same way that a central bank makes interest rate decisions, in this case focusing on balancing climate considerations with economic factors, as in point 1. A central carbon bank could also act via the UCC market to tighten or loosen supply mid-period if necessary. |
||
− | # Economic responsiveness |
||
− | #: Supply and demand in the UCC market would catalyse immediate response from business as it reacts to changes and attempts to stay competitive. |
||
− | # Real-time carbon labelling |
||
− | #: With modern supply chains, a product’s carbon price is kept up to date, from manufacture right through packaging, freight, and storage. The final carbon price to the end consumer is simply the accumulation of UCC costs that were added on and demanded in payment at each step in the supply chain. It results in a dynamic, responsive carbon price for everything with no requirement for official carbon price settings. |
||
− | # Transparency in the fossil fuel industry |
||
− | #: Metering of fossil fuel output by a central carbon authority would occur at the well-head or mine-shaft, in regular audits at the end of each rationing period. This gives a direct measure of the carbon entering the economy and CO<sub>2</sub> emissions produced. Progress would be clear to all. The significance of government or central carbon bank decision-making within this framework would also be readily understood. |
||
− | # Immediate driver of green innovation |
||
− | #: Progress towards a zero emissions economy under any circumstances is dependent on inventiveness and innovation. But in an un-rationed economy, even one with carbon taxes or pricing mechanisms, undesirable business stimuli can exist (usually due to government specific subsidies or taxes). This is generally down to the fact that non-rationing interventions have only partial coverage of the market. The comprehensive influence of UCCs on supply and demand for all products and services is a significant advantage over other climate action policies. |
||
− | # Facilitation and promotion of carbon drawdown |
||
− | #: The central carbon authority would pay for atmospheric CO<sub>2</sub> removal by paying UCCs weight for weight for proven carbon sequestration. This ‘negative emissions’ facility is the other side of the reduction system enabled by UCCs. Recipients (reforestation projects, carbon capture and sequestration industries) would be able to sell the UCCs they earn at the going rate. The higher the UCC price, the more it would promote carbon drawdown. |
||
− | # Unilateral (national within trading block) |
||
− | #: Any nation or trading bloc could immediately implement the UCC framework, where the customs authority sets up a proxy at the trading border to impose the UCC price required on incoming goods (which is paid by the importer). A successful implementation is more likely to lead to point 8 below. |
||
− | # Multilateral (international, between trading blocks, scaling to global) |
||
− | #: The ultimate goal and the most effective outcome is the implementation of the UCC framework across the global economy. This would provide society with the best chances of meeting the growing challenges that climate change represents. |
||
− | == |
+ | === Fossil Fuel Industry === |
+ | The other key actors in the system are the carbon producers - the oil, gas and coal suppliers. Supply-side control of fossil fuel extraction rates is the sole policy that directly limits carbon supply and guarantees decarbonisation. |
||
+ | Every gas or oil well and coal mine operation would be subject to upstream metering by the carbon authority to measure the quantity of fossil fuels extracted, for audit and payment of carbon token income. |
||
− | === Key Actors and Institutional Requirements === |
||
+ | The carbon producers would charge carbon tokens on their fossil fuel sales, weight for weight in tonnes, kilos and grammes of carbon, which is how the carbon tokens are denominated. The corporate accounts would be subject to audit by this central carbon authority. All carbon extracted – gas, oil, coal – would require surrender of the equivalent carbon tokens. |
||
− | A central carbon authority would be established, similar in function to a central bank. |
||
+ | Compliance in the whole carbon currency system would take place at the carbon producers, who become the lynchpin for policing of fossil fuel extraction and thus CO<sub>2</sub> emissions. It is the extraction of fossil fuels that is monitored and audited rather than their sale, because the fossil fuel producers in many cases use their own products to power their operations, or even allow their escape, e.g. methane leaks or flaring. |
||
− | This carbon bank would oversee the allocation of UCCs to citizens. |
||
+ | Downstream companies in the petrochemical industry and beyond in wider industry which do not extract fossil fuels would, by definition of the system, not be subject to metering or payment of carbon tokens to the carbon authority. |
||
− | It would administer the carbon ration post-allocation market where citizens and business come to sell surplus UCCs or obtain extra requirement. |
||
+ | === The Carbon Market === |
||
− | The carbon bank would also process the payment, audit and verification of UCCs from the carbon producers. |
||
+ | The ability to purchase extra carbon tokens from citizens or businesses would minimise problems when adaptation is slow or insufficient for whatever reason. |
||
+ | Wealthy citizens could buy extra carbon tokens to subsidise their carbon-heavy choices, but only what other people are selling, and that will decrease regularly as the carbon allowances are steadily reduced. Such a market for tokens is not a loophole that some observers might think prevents actual CO<sub>2</sub> emissions reduction from taking place, because firstly, not allowing the sale of tokens could encourage people who would otherwise be carbon-conscious to use up all their un-tradeable allowance on cheap high-carbon products. Secondly, the market for buying and selling carbon tokens represents a safety mechanism in the system that prevents people or businesses falling off a carbon “cliff edge” if they run out of tokens. |
||
− | Central banks across the globe are already putting in place the framework for an international digital reserve currency. This could be duplicated for the purposes of carbon rationing. |
||
+ | == Implementation == |
||
− | Carbon UCCs would not expire, so the central carbon authority would also monitor, manage and report on the carbon ration supply - the quantity of UCCs held by citizens and businesses. This information would feed back into the decision-making process for calculating the optimal quantity of UCCs to allocate at the start of each rationing period. |
||
+ | The carbon allowance policy can be implemented unilaterally by any nation, not requiring unanimous approval from hundreds of nations at the United Nations. |
||
+ | The roll-out could be implemented by central banks using digital currency frameworks – unilaterally by nation or within trading blocs by the creation of carbon borders with non-implementing trading partners, where customs authorities act as proxy and impose the carbon price on the domestic importers at the border. It could also be negotiated multilaterally with agreements on national carbon allowances via the existing UNFCCC-compliant GCI Contraction and Convergence treaty model. |
||
− | The other key actors in the UCC framework are the carbon producers. Every gas or oil well and coal mine operation would be subject to upstream metering by the carbon authority to measure the quantity of fossil fuels extracted and audit and payment of carbon ration income. |
||
+ | === The Central Carbon Authority === |
||
− | Compliance and policing of the whole carbon rationing system would take place through the carbon producers. |
||
+ | A central carbon authority would be established, similar in function to a central bank, to administer monetary control of the carbon currency. It would oversee the allocation of carbon allowances to citizens. |
||
+ | It would run the carbon market where citizens and business come to sell surplus tokens or obtain extra requirement. |
||
− | Downstream companies in the petrochemical industry and beyond in wider industry which do not extract fossil fuels would, by definition of the UCC framework, not be subject to metering or payment of UCCs to the carbon authority. |
||
+ | It would also process the payment, audit and verification of carbon tokens from the carbon producers. |
||
− | === Combination of Universal Basic Income, Personal Carbon Trading and a Carbon Currency === |
||
+ | Central banks across the globe are already putting in place the framework for an international digital reserve currency. This could be duplicated for the purposes of carbon allowances. |
||
− | Instead of collection and audit of UCCs by customer-facing retailers on behalf of the state, UCCs would flow via every business transaction through the supply chain from the end-carbon-consumer (citizen) to the original carbon producer (fossil fuel extractor). |
||
+ | Carbon tokens would not expire, so the carbon authority would also monitor, manage and report on the carbon currency supply - the quantity of carbon tokens held by citizens and businesses. This information would feed back into the decision-making process for calculating the optimal quantity of tokens to allocate for each period. |
||
− | The carbon providers would be subject to comprehensive monitoring of fossil fuel extraction. The carbon providers are the lynchpin in the UCC mechanism. For every tonne and kilo of fossil carbon extracted, the providers must surrender the same weight in UCCs to the central carbon authority. |
||
− | The carbon |
+ | The carbon authority would also mandate a negative interest rate on all carbon accounts to discourage stockpiling. |
+ | === National Implementation === |
||
− | https://carbonwatchdog.org/wp-content/uploads/CarbonCreditsSystem03.png |
||
+ | Any nation or trading bloc could immediately implement the policy, where the customs authority sets up a proxy at the trading border to impose the carbon price required on incoming goods (which is paid by the importer). A nation's national borders and customs agency would act as proxy for importers of foreign goods and services, collecting the required carbon tokens on imported goods from the buyers. |
||
+ | Other nations could join with the first nation at any point to form a larger trading block. |
||
− | The framework's original name “Total Carbon Rationing” contains the word “Total” because every product or service that is bought and sold is subject to the system: every vendor, every merchant, every shopkeeper, every business person who sells anything must put the UCCs on their product or service next to the usual price, even if it is truly a zero emissions product. |
||
+ | === International Implementation === |
||
− | Anybody or any business that burns carbon-based fuels would not be able to do so without paying the UCCs to the fuel supplier. The UCCs flow from citizens to energy companies in a direct chain of retail and wholesale commercial transactions. |
||
+ | The ultimate goal and the most effective situation would be the implementation of the policy across the global economy. This would provide society with the best chances of meeting the growing challenges that climate change represents. |
||
+ | One solution to provide an international basis for carbon allocation would be the Global Commons Initiative's Contraction and Convergence Framework<ref name=":4">Meyer, A.: ''GCI Contraction and Convergence Framework'' [http://www.gci.org.uk/ GCI.org.uk] (1992)</ref>. This is the essence of decades of international climate diplomacy, as used by UNFCCC, UK Government, the Brazilian, Russian, Indian, and Chinese delegations and as a basis for proposals by various organisations and political parties ever since<ref>Wikipedia: ''Contraction and Convergence'' [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Contraction_and_Convergence Wikipedia] (2019)</ref>. |
||
− | This establishes a direct link between the volume of UCCs allocated by the central carbon authority and the final CO<sub>2</sub> emissions produced in the economy in any one period. |
||
+ | On an international scale ultimately all citizens from all nations would receive the same individual allowance of carbon tokens. This would start differently for different countries yet end up the same by global agreement, using a UN-brokered convention based on the Contraction and Convergence system. |
||
− | UCCs would flow through the economy as a second parallel currency. It affects every product or service which exists and is for sale, requiring two figures on the price tag - a normal price tag in local currency - $, £, €, ¥ etc - and UCCs in tonnes and kgs of carbon. |
||
+ | The chart below shows, at the top, the annual rates of carbon emissions allocated (tonnes carbon per capita per country), and below, in gigatonnes of carbon total per country (from 2000). |
||
− | === Practical Example of UCC in Commerce === |
||
+ | It illustrates how national allocations can be negotiated to the satisfaction of all countries by commencing at different per capita levels and then converging at an agreed point before contracting. |
||
− | If a citizen wished to purchase a television, for instance, this is how UCC would affect the commercial process, resulting in the carbon producer becoming the key audit point for carbon rationing: |
||
+ | [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Contraction_and_Convergence https://upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/commons/2/22/Web_C%26C.png] |
||
− | # For simplicity's sake, imagine that the UK has implemented unilateral carbon rationing. The carbon authority will allocate all UK citizens an equal amount of UCCs, in absolute tonnes and kilos of carbon. |
||
− | # The carbon authority works closely with the UK HMRC (customs authority) to impose the carbon rationing system on all incoming goods and services from countries not in the system. |
||
− | # The customer chooses a TV, juggling the price and the UCCs required against the features wanted, and paying both money and UCCs in one transaction. The TV retailer decides what the ration should be. |
||
− | # The TV retailer receives the money and the UCCs, e.g. 500kg for the television in this example. |
||
− | # The TV retailer purchases the TV from the TV manufacturer, in a similar transaction of money and UCCs. The retailer would slightly increase the UCCs demanded, because it has to keep its shop warm in winter, and pay to transport the televisions. |
||
− | # The TV manufacturer built the TV from components, e.g. a plastic casing and a flat screen. |
||
− | # The flat screen for the sake of this example comes from China who are not yet in the system. The UK HMRC has an estimate of how much carbon was emitted in the making of the flat screen, and levies this amount at the border. Delivery to the TV manufacturer only occurs on payment of the UCCs to the HMRC. |
||
− | # The plastic casing was made in the UK and had its own price and ration, which the plastic manufacturer demands from the TV manufacturer. The plastic manufacturer uses considerable energy making the case, and bases the carbon ration for each plastic case produced on (a) the UCCs paid to the factory's energy provider and (b) the UCCs paid for the petrochemicals it converted into plastic. |
||
− | # The energy provider could be using gas or coal or wind or nuclear, but in this example uses North Sea gas. |
||
− | # The energy provider bought the gas wholesale from BP for example and paid BP the money price and a tonne of UCCs per tonne of North Sea gas bought. |
||
− | # At the year end, BP must pay the carbon authority a tonne of UCCs for every tonne of carbon in the gas it pumped out of the North Sea gas fields. |
||
− | # If any actor in the process runs out of UCCs for whatever reason, they would have to purchase the extra UCCs on the open carbon ration market, which is regulated by the carbon authority, but whose price level is set by supply and demand in the market. |
||
+ | === Cost of Implementation === |
||
− | === Impact on the Supply Chain in Business and Industry === |
||
+ | Compared to the “free” option of doing nothing or “business as usual”, the carbon allowance policy has a large, up-front cost with manageable, contained, on-going running costs similar to VAT or German MwSt. |
||
+ | Compared to carbon tax policies, the large up-front cost comes as business, government and citizens prepare for its introduction. Studies in 2008 in the UK and more recent studies on projects such a road traffic in Kenya and local transport in Finland show that costs are not prohibitive. |
||
− | The introduction of carbon rationing would not be a totally unprecedented introduction. In 1971, the United Kingdom decimalised its currency and dropped the non-decimal shilling. Then in 1973, it introduced VAT, and in 1978 started mandating metric measurements. In 1990, the sovereign nations of East and West Germany reunified, completely replacing the Ost-Mark with the D-Mark. In 1999, Germany did it again with 10 other European nations to introduce the Euro. |
||
+ | But taxes, trading schemes, legislative bans or subsidy programs have significant running costs to maintain the level of carbon policymaking that rationing would make redundant: |
||
− | If introduced, every citizen and every business would have to become adept at handling carbon ration weights in the same way as money. Just as income and expenditure of money is key to good financial management, the same would be true of income and expenditure of UCCs. |
||
− | |||
− | For citizens, each would receive a personal allocation at the start of each rationing period and must ensure they live within their budget. |
||
− | |||
− | Business on the other hand would be required to charge and procure all UCCs from its customers, which it would carefully manage to cover all of its own ration expenditure. From the technological perspective, business would be compelled to introduce accounting software to account for carbon ration income and expenditure. |
||
− | |||
− | The banking industry would undoubtedly understand the need for dual transactions where money and carbon ration transactions are carried out in parallel. |
||
− | |||
− | === Methane Control under the UCC Framework === |
||
− | |||
− | CH4 is a highly potent greenhouse gas, 28 times greater than CO<sub>2</sub> over 100 years (or 84x over 20).<ref>US EPA: '''Understanding Global Warming Potentials''' ([https://www.epa.gov/ghgemissions/understanding-global-warming-potentials United States Environmental Protection Agency])</ref> |
||
− | |||
− | To control it under UCC, businesses wishing to emit CH4 would need to be licensed for the quantity emitted in C0<sub>2</sub>e (CO<sub>2</sub> equivalent) weight, paid for in UCCs. |
||
− | |||
− | Methane leakages from fossil fuel extraction and mining for minerals such as copper<ref>Azadi, M. et al 2020: '''Transparency on greenhouse gas emissions from mining to enable climate change mitigation''' ([https://www.nature.com/articles/s41561-020-0531-3 Nature Geoscience])</ref> represent another problematic area. Based on experience with past mining or drilling operations and including geological data indicating potential methane leakage from oil or coal beds, average methane leakage at any extraction site could be calculated and the appropriate UCCs added to the final bill at the carbon producer's audit by the carbon authority. |
||
− | |||
− | Oil and gas wells and coal mines would be metered as described above under a UCC regime to measure the UCCs due to the carbon authority for CO<sub>2</sub> emissions, but the direct release of CH4 into the atmosphere would be 28 times more damaging than the CO<sub>2</sub>. |
||
− | |||
− | Third party monitoring operations led to the detection of the massive CH4 leaks from Exxon wells in Ohio<ref>Pinckard, C. 2019: '''Satellite data shows Ohio methane leak one of largest ever recorded''' ([https://www.cleveland.com/nation/2019/12/satellite-data-shows-ohio-methane-leak-one-of-largest-ever-recorded-reports-say.html Cleveland.com News Agency])</ref> and from Texas<ref>Kessel, J.M., Tabuchi, H. 2019: '''Texas Methane Super-emitters''' ([https://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2019/12/12/climate/texas-methane-super-emitters.html ])</ref>. Such monitoring would need to become the norm. |
||
− | |||
− | Methane emissions from livestock is another big source globally. A farmer with a dairy or beef herd would be required to pay license fees in UCCs per head of cattle. |
||
− | |||
− | Methane emissions from solid waste management and composting are also a significant global source of anthropogenic CH4. Remote sensing is already used in California, USA as part of pollution control research.<ref>IOPScience 2020: '''Using remote sensing to detect, validate, and quantify methane emissions from California solid waste operations''' ([https://iopscience.iop.org/article/10.1088/1748-9326/ab7b99])</ref> |
||
− | |||
− | === Preservation of Natural Carbon Sinks and Prospects for Negative Emissions === |
||
− | |||
− | The continued destruction of the globally significant carbon sinks, such as the rainforests of the Amazon, Borneo and the Congo, represent a large risk to any attempts to control CO<sub>2</sub> emissions globally. |
||
− | |||
− | The agreement and introduction of UCC could provide a UCCs-based income to the owners or guardians of every standing forest. The forest carbon sinks sequester about 15 per cent of anthropogenic carbon dioxide emissions<ref>Hubau, W., Lewis, S. et al 2020: '''Asynchronous carbon sink saturation in African and Amazonian tropical forests''' ([https://www.nature.com/articles/s41586-020-2035-0 Nature])</ref>, although that rate is falling. From the opposite perspective, deforestation for economic gain would have to be monitored and audited by the carbon authority, which would then demand the equivalent UCCs from the agent carrying out the deforestation. The UCC principle maintains that carbon usage in the economy must be paid for in UCCs, weight for weight. |
||
− | |||
− | The obvious culprit here is the palm oil industry with its extensive oil palm plantations, along with timber production, soya or beef farming forest clearance methods, and other drivers of deforestation. Unsustainable agricultural practices by indigenous farmers though would still be a problem. |
||
− | |||
− | The demand for biofuels would also be channelled into sustainable practices. Industrial biofuel agriculture<ref>FAO, 2008: '''FAO The State of Food and Agriculture, Part I: Biofuels: Prospects, Risks and Opportunities''' ([http://www.fao.org/docrep/011/i0100e/i0100e00.htm FAO])</ref> would need to budget for payment of UCCs for CO<sub>2</sub> loss due to soil degradation. Large woodchip-fired power stations would pay in UCCs for woodchip from forestry operations, who would be subject to audit and ration payment to the carbon authority for the forest clearance. Future developments with current 2020 policies could otherwise lead to unchecked deforestation.<ref>Sandbag, 2019: '''Playing With Fire: assessment of company plans to burn biomass in EU coal power stations''' ([https://sandbag.org.uk/project/playing-with-fire/ Sandbag])</ref><ref>Carbon Pulse, 2019: '''EU’s wood-fired power should face carbon price under tougher rules''' ([http://carbon-pulse.com/88900/ Carbon Pulse News Agency])</ref> |
||
− | |||
− | In parallel to the requirement for keeping forests standing, UCC offers a huge potential as a mechanism to pay for negative emissions. For instance, all deforested land across the globe could be reforested. As trees grow, they absorb CO<sub>2</sub> from the atmosphere. Reforestation projects should be able to claim this weight of absorbed CO<sub>2</sub> as UCCs from the carbon authority. |
||
− | |||
− | Obviously under the rationing mechanism, forest stewards of both intact primary forest and regrowing secondary forest would have to be subject to stringent control to the same degree as the gas/oil/coal carbon producers. |
||
− | |||
− | The forest condition and the amount of carbon absorbed (or lost through felling) would be monitored by remote sensing in the same way that forests are currently monitored.<ref>Bae, S., Levick, S.R., Heidrich, L. et al. '''Radar vision in the mapping of forest biodiversity from space.''' ([https://www.nature.com/articles/s41467-019-12737-x Nat Commun 10, 4757 (2019) doi:10.1038/s41467-019-12737-x])</ref><ref>Almeida D. et al, 2019: '''Monitoring the structure of forest restoration plantations with a drone-lidar system''' ([https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0303243418311954 International Journal of Applied Earth Observation and Geoinformation])</ref> |
||
− | |||
− | == The Whole is Greater than the Sum of the Policy Parts == |
||
− | |||
− | === Superiority over Carbon Taxes and Carbon Pricing Mechanisms === |
||
− | |||
− | There is little discussion of carbon rationing as a macro-economic policy, compared to the attention given to carbon taxes or carbon pricing policies. There is an implicit assumption that the reach of carbon rationing is restricted to consumer-citizens and that a large part of the carbon economy would be not be impacted, e.g. aviation, shipping, imported emissions, in-built emissions, government services, the military. UCC as an enhanced rationing mechanism produces an impact comprehensively across these sectors. |
||
− | |||
− | In the UK in 2008, the British Government Home Office began developing plans to bring in carbon rationing to combat rising CO<sub>2</sub> emissions. <ref>Miliband, D. 2007: '''Personal Carbon Allowances Speech, Audit Commission Annual Lecture''' ([https://web.archive.org/web/20070205235502/http://www.defra.gov.uk/corporate/ministers/speeches/david-miliband/dm060719.htm Web Archive])</ref><ref>Miliband, D. 2006: '''Ministerial Blog of Home Secretary, UK Gov''' ([https://web.archive.org/web/20070212071404/http://www.davidmiliband.defra.gov.uk/blogs/ministerial_blog/archive/2006/07/19/1557.aspx Web Archive])</ref> The plans were abandoned after the then Home Secretary David Milliband changed roles within government. |
||
− | |||
− | Carbon taxation and pricing schemes aim to influence economic carbon demand via increases in carbon-related costs to commerce and industry. This layer of indirection based on the artificial manipulation of supply prices is also far from perfect because it is not comprehensively applied to all carbon outlets and it suffers due to the uncertain sensitivity of supply and demand.<ref>Gordon, S. 2012 '''Econ 101: What you need to know about carbon taxes and cap-and-trade''' ([https://www.macleans.ca/economy/business/why-the-difference-between-carbon-taxes-and-cap-and-trade-isnt-as-important-as-you-think/ Macleans Canadian Current Affairs Magazine])</ref> |
||
− | |||
− | It is also quite complex and difficult to construct a carbon pricing system and then to implement it. Multiple issues occur, especially on a political level e.g. in British Columbia, Canada<ref>Corkall, V., Gass, P. 2019: '''Locked In and Losing Out: British Columbia’s fossil fuel subsidies''' ([https://www.iisd.org/library/locked-in-losing-out IISD])</ref><ref>Campbell, K. 2019: '''Amid calls for stronger carbon levy, P.E.I. PCs vow to keep cutting gas taxes''' ([https://www.cbc.ca/news/canada/prince-edward-island/pei-carbon-levy-1.5395932 CBC News])</ref>, in the EU<ref>Just, S. 2017: '''The carbon price thaw: Post freeze future of GB carbon price''' ([https://www.auroraer.com/insight/carbon-price-thaw-post-freeze-future-gb-carbon-price-2/ Aurora Energy Research])</ref>. |
||
− | |||
− | The measure of the inefficiency or the not-yet-internalised costs of climate change-induced damage is known as the '''carbon price gap'''. As of 2019, this stands at a massive 87% of all carbon emissions.<ref>Jenkins, J. 2019: '''Why Carbon Pricing Falls Short''' ([https://kleinmanenergy.upenn.edu/policy-digests/why-carbon-pricing-falls-short Kleinman Center for Energy Policy])</ref>. See also the World Bank carbon pricing dashboard.<ref>World Bank 2020: '''Carbon Pricng Dashboard''' ([https://carbonpricingdashboard.worldbank.org/map_data Washington DC: World Bank])</ref> |
||
− | |||
− | === Redundancy of Many Carbon Regulations under UCC === |
||
− | |||
− | The UK Committee on Climate Change produced an extensive and wide-ranging document<ref>UK Committee on Climate Change 2019: '''Net Zero 2050 Strategy''' ([https://www.theccc.org.uk/publication/net-zero-the-uks-contribution-to-stopping-global-warming/ UKCCC])</ref> outlining a policy path to achieve net zero CO<sub>2</sub> emissions by 2050 and immediately realised 2 problems: were their recommendations plausible<ref>UK Parliament Commons Select Committee 2019: '''Government’s target for ‘net-zero’ by 2050 undeliverable unless clean growth policies introduced''' ([https://www.parliament.uk/business/committees/committees-a-z/commons-select/science-and-technology-committee/news-parliament-2017/clean-growth-report-published-17-19/ UK Parliament])</ref> and are they even the best choice?<ref>Workman, M. et al 2019: '''Decision making in contexts of deep uncertainty - An alternative approach for long-term climate policy''' ([https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S1462901119304319 Science Direct])</ref> |
||
− | |||
− | UCC would allow decision-makers to focus on how much carbon emissions to allow, rather than a thousand other things. Already academic policy analysts predict that governments will be unable to rise to the challenge without fundamental organisational restructuring.<ref>University of Exeter Energy Policy Group 2020: '''Delivering Net Zero''' ([http://geography.exeter.ac.uk/media/universityofexeter/schoolofgeography/images/researchgroups/epg/Delivering_Net_Zero.pdf PDF Download])</ref> |
||
− | |||
− | A further problem with regulation-based policies is the extended time horizons associated with such policies. The EU in 2020 displayed a particularly egregious example of this. The implementation of the 'EU Green New Deal' will only take force 10 years down the line in 2030 and it does not allow for greater ambition until 2035.<ref>Abnett, K. 2020-03-02: '''Environment groups say EU's planned climate law means a lost decade''' ([https://www.reuters.com/article/us-climate-change-eu/environment-groups-say-eus-planned-climate-law-means-a-lost-decade-idUSKBN20P28A Reuters])</ref> |
||
− | |||
− | So many of the discussions in the field of national and consumer climate policy would be rendered redundant by the automated ration setting mechanism of UCC in all supply chains. See the next section. |
||
− | |||
− | === Implementation and Running Costs === |
||
− | |||
− | Compared to the “free” option of doing nothing or “business as usual”, UCC has a large, up-front cost with manageable, contained, on-going running costs similar to VAT or German MwSt. |
||
− | |||
− | Doing nothing but rely on technological developments to bring about the obsolescence of fossil fuels is a policy that research shows cannot keep global warming below 3.0°C. This will bring global economic recessions along with damage and adaptation costs in the order of trillions of US dollars. |
||
− | |||
− | Compared to carbon taxes and carbon pricing strategies, UCC has a large up-front cost as business, government and citizens prepare for its introduction. Studies in 2008 in the UK and more recent studies on projects such a road traffic in Kenya and local transport in Finland show that costs are not prohibitive.<ref>Al-Guthmy F.M.O., Yan W. 2021: '''Financial implications of mobile phone-based personal carbon trading: a case study of Safaricom''' ([https://doi.org/10.1088/2634-4505/ac0350 Environmental Research: Infrastructure and Sustainability Jul 1;1(1):015002])</ref><ref>Urban Innovation Actions 2021: '''Sustainable Urban Mobility through Citizens Cap-and-trade Initiative''' ([https://www.uia-initiative.eu/en/uia-cities/lahti UIA])</ref> |
||
− | |||
− | But taxes, trading schemes and legislative bans or subsidy programs have significant running costs to maintain the level of carbon policymaking that rationing would make redundant: |
||
* establishing what citizens and industry have to stop doing |
* establishing what citizens and industry have to stop doing |
||
Line 197: | Line 107: | ||
* implementing the laws |
* implementing the laws |
||
* monitoring the effects |
* monitoring the effects |
||
− | * |
+ | * constantly strengthening the laws in the face of political opposition |
− | And all this would be repeated |
+ | And all this would be repeated for each individual policy for every nation in the world. |
− | So the carbon tax alternatives are initially cheaper, but they have higher legislative costs as governments manage decarbonisation, legislating year after year to keep up with economic and technological developments and unforeseen issues. The longer it lasts, the more likely it is that |
+ | So the carbon tax alternatives are initially cheaper, but they have higher legislative costs as governments manage decarbonisation, legislating year after year to keep up with economic and technological developments and unforeseen issues. The longer it lasts, the more likely it is that the carbon allowance policy turns out cheaper. |
+ | The costs to the state and increase in taxes required to implement the system would be small in comparison to the billions proposed for climate-related subsidies and government spending programmes. |
||
− | There are other costs associated with policing UCC, for instance satellite monitoring of forests. This is already carried out by space agencies, which is how the world became aware of the 2019 Amazon fires. Much of these costs exist already. |
||
+ | == Advantages == |
||
− | === Transparency via Automatic Generation of Carbon Price on Price Tag === |
||
+ | No requirement for carbon labelling laws: the carbon price of every item creates itself via cumulative addition up the supply chain. The system results in a dynamic, responsive carbon price for everything with no requirement for government to research and label everything with a fixed, statutory carbon price. |
||
− | People and green businesses base their consumer choices on information that is often not on the label, is incomplete, or worse, is misleading or purposefully suppressed. |
||
+ | Transparency in commerce: people and green businesses currently base their consumer choices on information that is often not on the label, is incomplete, or worse, is misleading or purposefully suppressed. Very few things have the same carbon transparency as buying a tank of fuel to drive somewhere. There are unexpected inputs, hidden subsidies and incalculable interactions which make some things' actual carbon footprint differ radically from the expected. This system's cumulative supply chain carbon price irons out these issues and distributes the effort of setting the carbon price to the place where it is most easily done - by the people creating the product or delivering the service. |
||
− | The New York Times bestseller "How Bad are Bananas?"<ref>Berners-Lee, M. 2010: '''How Bad are Bananas?''' ([https://profilebooks.com/how-bad-are-bananas.html Profile Books])</ref> picked out a highly diverse mix of 100 articles or activities, giving an analysis of the carbon footprint of each. It demonstrates the challenge faced when trying to gather this sort of information. |
||
+ | Transparency in the fossil fuel industry: the metering of fossil fuel extraction at source gives a direct measure of the carbon entering the economy and the CO<sub>2</sub> emissions produced. Progress would be clear to all. The significance of government or central carbon bank decision-making within the system would also be readily understood. |
||
− | Very few things have the same carbon transparency as buying a tank of fuel to drive somewhere. There are unexpected inputs, hidden subsidies and incalculable interactions which make something's actual carbon footprint differ radically from the expected. |
||
+ | Direct control over fossil fuel supply: because there is a one-to-one relationship between carbon tokens and the all the oil, gas or coal that fossil fuel producers are permitted to extract from the ground, the government's control over how much fossil fuel is produced and how much CO<sub>2</sub> is emitted is direct, unlike the situation with carbon tax, where the impact on CO<sub>2</sub> emissions is dependent on the economy's reaction to the carbon tax. |
||
− | UCC would make the carbon producers the ultimate recipients of UCCs, for which they are audited by the carbon authority to assure compliance between the quantity of fossil fuels extracted from the ground and the quantity of UCCs that they procure via their sales of those fuels. |
||
+ | Driver of green innovation: progress towards a zero emissions economy in any circumstances will only occur at a fast enough pace if inventiveness and innovation can be harnessed to create new methods and processes. Because every individual will develop a solid carbon literacy through their everyday use of their own personal carbon account, people will bring this into their work and drive the economy's adaptation to the system from the inside out. Compare this with the impact of carbon taxes: worldwide implementation of carbon taxes in 2020 covered only 16% of the economy, leaving the "carbon price gap" standing at 84%<ref name=":5">World Bank 2020: '''State and Trends of Carbon Pricing 2020''' ([https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/33809 World Bank, Washington DC])</ref>. The coverage of the proposed carbon currency system would be practically 100%. So the inherent "price signal" for carbon under the carbon currency system would be 5 times stronger than from carbon taxes as it stands. The stronger impact would accelerate business adaptation and innovation. |
||
− | There is an example given above of how UCCs would flow through the economy. To demonstrate the point regarding information on CO<sub>2</sub> emissions produced per product/service even more simply, here is a example describing "widgets" carbon ration valuation: |
||
+ | Cross-border trade: any nation or trading bloc using this system instructs its customs authority to set up a proxy at the border to impose an estimated carbon price on incoming goods, which is paid by the importer. |
||
− | # A business manufactures widgets. It has to calculate the carbon ration per widget. |
||
− | # It produces widgets from components. |
||
− | # Component A has a carbon ration of 0.3kg |
||
− | # Component B has a carbon ration of 0.5kg |
||
− | # The business has to pay its energy supplier per quarter with UCCs and money, which both must be obtained from its customers. |
||
− | # The calculation is: the UCCs per widget = the UCCs needed for components plus the UCCs paid for energy per quarter divided by the number of widgets produced per quarter. |
||
− | # The energy supplier purchases fuel for power generation from the carbon producers, paying UCCs weight for weight according to the fuel required. It demands UCCs from its customers proportionate to their energy usage. |
||
− | # The widget company also has to pay for the diesel for its delivery lorry at 0.1kg ration per widget. |
||
− | # The diesel supplier pays the UCCs direct to the carbon producer. |
||
− | # As a result the carbon ration for each widget is set at 1kg. |
||
− | # The costs of components A and B were calculated similarly by their manufacturers. |
||
+ | Facilitation and promotion of carbon drawdown: the government has a national budget for carbon allowances which it uses to allocate every citizen's allowance. It can pay in carbon tokens from this budget for atmospheric CO<sub>2</sub> removal, e.g. in soils via sustainable farming practices, rewilding, the protection of ocean carbon sinks or any kind of mechanical carbon drawdown. Recipients would be able to sell the carbon tokens they earn at the going rate. The higher the carbon token price, the more it would promote carbon drawdown. |
||
− | A further benefit is that the business can update the UCCs demanded for their product as soon as component A or component B changes, or when they sign up to a carbon neutral energy provider, or exchange their diesel lorry for an electric vehicle. |
||
+ | Introduction of system is no cause for alarm: the introductory level of carbon tokens allocated for the personal allowance would be adequate to bring about familiarity with the carbon currency without entailing an immediate change in the average person's lifestyle choices. Only the most profligate carbon emitters would actually find themselves restricted during the first years of the system's implementation. This tends to be a small number of wealthy people who constitute only a tiny proportion of the electorate. Most would agree such people should rein in their carbon-intensive activities. |
||
− | === Dynamic Stimulation of Low Carbon Industry === |
||
+ | Long term impacts ameliorated by advances in technology: it is probable that the progress of green technologies in the future will reduce the required carbon tokens in many sectors, cushioning the impact on consumers when allowance reductions start to cause real impact |
||
− | It's simpler, more efficient and more direct to control the carbon '''quantity''' in the economy than the carbon price, which is fundamentally a difficult policy making exercise<ref>Beugin, D. 2016: '''Carbon Pricing and Innovation''' ([https://ecofiscal.ca/2016/10/26/carbon-pricing-innovation/ Ecofiscal Commission, Canada])</ref> and prone to failure and political intervention due to the inherent lack of certainty, flexibility, and stringency in such policies. |
||
+ | == Comparison with other approaches == |
||
− | Climate policies that don't restrict supply (taxes, legislation, sector-based emissions trading schemes) are demand-based measures that only impact certain aspects of the economy while leaving others untouched, with no guarantees about consumer behaviour and progress of decarbonisation. |
||
+ | Carbon tax is always criticised for its unfairness because those with lower incomes generally end up paying proportionately more of their income for it, but carbon allowances are allocated equally per capita, and allow those on low incomes who have on average smaller carbon footprints to profit from selling their excess. |
||
− | + | The worldwide implementation of carbon taxes and ETS schemes in 2020 covered only 16% of the economy, leaving the "carbon price gap" standing at 84%<ref name=":5" />. The coverage of the proposed carbon currency system would be practically 100%. So the inherent "price signal" for carbon under the carbon currency system would be 5 times stronger than from carbon taxes as it stands. The stronger impact would accelerate business adaptation and innovation. |
|
+ | It is also quite complex and difficult to construct a carbon pricing system and then to implement it using policies that can only implement partial coverage. Multiple issues occur, especially on a political level e.g. in British Columbia, Canada<ref name=":6">Corkall, V., Gass, P. 2019: '''Locked In and Losing Out: British Columbia’s fossil fuel subsidies''' ([https://www.iisd.org/library/locked-in-losing-out IISD])</ref><ref name=":7">Campbell, K. 2019: '''Amid calls for stronger carbon levy, P.E.I. PCs vow to keep cutting gas taxes''' ([https://www.cbc.ca/news/canada/prince-edward-island/pei-carbon-levy-1.5395932 CBC News])</ref>, in the EU<ref name=":8">Just, S. 2017: '''The carbon price thaw: Post freeze future of GB carbon price''' ([https://www.auroraer.com/insight/carbon-price-thaw-post-freeze-future-gb-carbon-price-2/ Aurora Energy Research])</ref>. |
||
− | While one business catalyst is obviously the higher carbon costs due to the reduction of the carbon ration supply, both private citizens and commercial interests would benefit significantly from the boost to their "carbon literacy"<ref>Fawcett T. and Parag Y. 2010: '''Personal Carbon Trading''' ([https://doi.org/10.4324/9781849776721 Taylor & Francis])</ref>, as everyone educates themselves about the complexities surrounding CO<sub>2</sub> emissions in the economy and the ways and means of reducing their dependence on costly UCCs. Higher levels of knowledge are the driver of innovation. |
||
+ | Other attempts to control society's widespread and deeply rooted CO<sub>2</sub> emissions via the creation of a multitude of decarbonisation mandates in government have also not had the desired effect. The problem with regulation-based policies is the extended time horizons associated with such policies. The EU in 2020 displayed a particularly egregious example of this. The implementation of the 'EU Green New Deal' will only take force 10 years down the line in 2030 and it does not allow for greater ambition until 2035.<ref name=":3">Abnett, K.: ''Environment groups say EU's planned climate law means a lost decade'' [https://www.reuters.com/article/us-climate-change-eu/environment-groups-say-eus-planned-climate-law-means-a-lost-decade-idUSKBN20P28A Reuters] (2020)</ref> |
||
− | === Fairness and Equitability === |
||
+ | The carbon allowances policy has an advantage over every other kind of carbon pricing policy, because other policies attempt to guess the “right” price for carbon, without knowing in advance how great its impact will be, because they are not comprehensively applied to all sources of CO<sub>2</sub> emissions and they suffer from variations in the sensitivity of supply and demand. We roughly know the quantity of CO<sub>2</sub> emissions we can allow for various global warming scenarios, so it is more robust approach to use that figure to set a per capita allowance. |
||
− | Rationing is categorised by economists as a fundamentally progressive fiscal policy. Studies looking at rationing in the 1940s and 1950s show this. |
||
− | <ref name="RationingReturns">Roodhouse, M. 2007: '''Rationing returns: a solution to global warming?''' ([http://www.historyandpolicy.org/policy-papers/papers/rationing-returns-a-solution-to-global-warming History and Policy, Kings College London])</ref> |
||
+ | Many climate policy discussions would be solved by this policy's broad coverage. It's simpler, more efficient and more direct to control the quantity of carbon entering the economy than the carbon price, which is fundamentally a difficult policy making exercise, prone to failure and political intervention. They rely on inclusions and exclusions on a sector by sector basis and variation in carbon accounting practices dependent on national law. Carbon allowances on the other hand would provide comprehensive coverage of the economy and a comparatively small set of economic indicators, influences and unknowns. This would provide the backdrop for a reliable investment framework that gives a clear pathway for innovation towards carbon neutrality. |
||
− | To prevent anybody being unfairly affected by rationing, the government would hold back a percentage of everybody’s carbon ration allocation. This can be used to supplement those in extra need of UCCs through no fault of their own. |
||
+ | Shipping illustrates a typical problem businesses face. The International Maritime Organisation brokered a international agreement that shipping fuel must be used more efficiently by 2020, but despite 20 years preparation, it is on the verge of failure because of disagreement over who bears responsibility in the industry<ref>Financial Times, 2019-11-14: '''What we can learn from the 2020 shipping fuel switch''' ([https://www.ft.com/content/4c3e5fdc-0601-11ea-a984-fbbacad9e7dd Financial Times])</ref>. The carbon allowances policy would enable an individual nation to include shipping under its umbrella via the customs proxy mechanism described above to solve international responsibility issue, and the fuel costs would carry the carbon costs, solving the ownership issue. |
||
− | On an international scale, all citizens from all nations would receive the same individual allocation of UCCs. This would start differently for different countries yet end up the same by global agreement, using a UN-brokered convention based on the Global Commons Institute’s Contraction and Convergence framework. |
||
+ | == Appendix 1: Also Known As == |
||
− | Wealthy citizens could buy extra UCCs to subsidise their carbon-heavy choices, but only what other people are selling, and that will decrease regularly as the rationing continues. Such a market for UCCs is not a loophole preventing actual CO<sub>2</sub> emissions reduction from taking place. Firstly, limiting trading could encourage people who would otherwise be carbon-conscious to use up all their untradable allowance on cheap high-carbon products. Secondly, the market for buying and selling UCCs represents a safety mechanism in the system that prevents people or businesses falling off a carbon ration “cliff edge” by running out of UCCs. |
||
+ | The system's original name “Total Carbon Rationing” contains the word “Total” because every product or service that is bought and sold is subject to the system: every vendor, every merchant, every shopkeeper, every business person who sells anything must put the carbon price on their product or service next to the usual price, even if it is truly a zero emissions product. |
||
+ | It was later given the title "Universal Carbon Credits". |
||
− | === A More Robust Future for Carbon Drawdown, the Carbon Offsetting Industry and the Voluntary Carbon Markets === |
||
+ | In 2022, following professional advice, we developed a communications strategy that called for simpler vocabulary: hence it became the "carbon currency based on carbon allowances". |
||
− | The harsh reality of CO<sub>2</sub> emissions and prospects for their reduction means any realistic plan must include removing CO<sub>2</sub> from the atmosphere, or global warming will overshoot 1.5°C.<ref>Andrew, R. 2019: '''Global Carbon Budget 2019''' ([http://folk.uio.no/roberan/GCB2019.shtml CICERO Center for International Climate Research])</ref> |
||
+ | == Appendix 2: Central carbon authority == |
||
− | This chart displays the Global Carbon Budget. It shows annual global CO<sub>2</sub> emissions on the Y axis in gigatonnes. As of writing, the thick black curve has risen every year up to 2019 on the X axis. The cumulative effect of all emissions to date has resulted in a global temperature rise of 1°C above pre-industrial levels. |
||
+ | By setting a CO<sub>2</sub> emissions reduction goal and distributing the carbon allowances that achieve this reduction, a nation has a policy tool that acts as an economic tuning mechanism allowing the rate of CO<sub>2</sub> emissions reduction to be balanced against any negative impacts it causes. The goal should be to keep reduction rates at the highest economically feasible level. Faced with deteriorating climatic conditions or sea level changes for example, or unexpected synergies appearing with the growth of the low carbon economy, adjusting the size of the next carbon allowances budget gives a straightforward lever to soft-pedal or step up decarbonisation. |
||
+ | ==Appendix 3: Practical example of carbon token usage in commerce== |
||
− | The 2015 Paris Climate Agreement between all nations in the world targets a 1.5°C limit to global warming, with initial commitments to keep the temperature rise "well below 2°C". |
||
+ | For simplicity’s sake, imagine that the UK has implemented the policy unilaterally. The UK carbon authority will then work in tandem with the customs authorities to impose the carbon token price on all goods and services coming in from other countries. Now say you want to buy a television, for instance. How do the carbon tokens fit into the commercial process? |
||
− | According to the latest climate science, to achieve a limit of 1.5°C warming, society must restrict further CO<sub>2</sub> emissions to less than 420 gigatonnes. The downward-arcing black line on the chart displays how annual emissions must decline if we adhere to the 420 gigatonne total. In other words, with current emissions at 42 gigatonnes per year, if we carried on for another 10 years, we would then need to completely stop all emissions or global warming would exceed 1.5°C. |
||
+ | # The UK carbon authority has allocated all citizens an equal amount of carbon tokens, reflecting absolute tonnes and kilos of carbon. When you choose a TV in a retail outlet, the price tag will show both the price in sterling and the price in tokens, and in all the preceding business transactions leading to the TV arriving in the shop, there will have been these joint costs – money and tokens. |
||
− | https://folk.uio.no/roberan/t/i/mitigation_curves_1.5C_191203.png |
||
+ | # The TV is made from component parts, some originating in the UK, others from abroad. The plastic casing, in this example, was made in the UK so already has incurred a carbon cost which the case-maker will need to recoup when the TV manufacturer buys it. Making the case used a lot of energy and requires plastic, so the case manufacturer worked out the carbon cost in tokens by adding (a) the tokens paid to the energy provider, and (b) the tokens paid for the petrochemicals to make the plastic. |
||
+ | # The energy provider might be using gas or coal, wind or nuclear, but let’s say it’s North Sea gas from BP, so the energy provider had to pay BP the tokens per tonne of gas bought. BP is one end of this production chain, and will be paying the UK carbon authority carbon tokens representing a tonne of carbon for every tonne of carbon in the gas it pumps out of the North Sea. |
||
+ | # Other components of this TV have been imported from outside the UK, from countries not yet in the system – the flat screen, for example, has come from China. The UK customs officer has an estimate of how much carbon was emitted in the making of the flat screen, and levies this amount at the border. Delivery to the TV manufacturer only occurs on payment of the required tokens to the UK customs authority. |
||
+ | # The TV manufacturing business has now bought the component parts, paying the required tokens, and makes the television, using more energy. |
||
+ | # The final calculation for the TV manufacturer is: carbon price = ( tokens needed for parts + tokens paid for energy ) |
||
+ | # All tokens expended must be recouped from its customer, the retailer. |
||
+ | # Now the retailer purchases the television from the manufacturer, paying the tokens required, and prices it for sale, slightly increasing the tokens demanded of the final customer because it has to keep its shop warm in winter, and pay to transport the televisions. |
||
+ | # Finally you, the customer, go to the retailer and choose the television, gauging the price as usual and also the carbon price in tokens, and paying both money and tokens in one transaction. |
||
+ | # So the four-step cumulative carbon price in tokens for the TV looks like this: |
||
+ | #* A for the energy costs, in tokens, for North Sea gas extracted by BP, paid first by the energy provider and then after the energy is generated, by the plastic case manufacturer |
||
+ | #* plus B for the added carbon costs of the imported screen and other component parts, paid for by the TV manufacturer |
||
+ | #* plus C for the energy costs of production, added by the TV manufacturer |
||
+ | #* and finally D for the extra energy costs of storage and transport added by the retailer. |
||
+ | # All four costs are eventually met by the customer’s token purchase price. |
||
+ | # Passing on the cost of carbon priced in tokens in this way makes the primary carbon producers (in this case BP) the ultimate recipients of tokens, and the key audit point – regular audits will be carried out by the carbon authority to assure compliance between the quantity of fossil fuels extracted from the ground and the tokens that they procure via their sales of those fuels. |
||
+ | ==Appendix 4: Methane control under the carbon allowances system== |
||
− | As the chart text states, such sudden emissions reduction is practically impossible. The only way to keep the total extra anthropogenic CO<sub>2</sub> added to the atmosphere below 420 Gigatonnes from 2020 is to pull CO<sub>2</sub> out of the atmosphere - "negative emissions", in the appropriate huge quantities. |
||
+ | CH4 is a highly potent greenhouse gas, 28 times greater than CO<sub>2</sub> over 100 years (or 84x over 20)<ref>US EPA: '''Understanding Global Warming Potentials''' ([https://www.epa.gov/ghgemissions/understanding-global-warming-potentials United States Environmental Protection Agency])</ref>. Methane leakages from fossil fuel extraction, mining for minerals such as copper<ref>Azadi, M. et al 2020: '''Transparency on greenhouse gas emissions from mining to enable climate change mitigation''' ([https://www.nature.com/articles/s41561-020-0531-3 Nature Geoscience])</ref>, farming of ruminant mammals, solid waste management and several other activities are problematic areas for emissions control policies due to the significant quantities of non-CO<sub>2</sub> greenhouse gases that are emitted. In most cases though they are already well-regulated industries, so lending themselves to coverage by the carbon allowances system. This can be done by licensing the operation to emit greenhouse gases against purchase of a license, priced in carbon tokens according to the quantity to be emitted, calculated as C0<sub>2</sub>e (CO<sub>2</sub> equivalent). |
||
− | Under UCC, the central carbon bank would promote “negative emissions” by awarding UCCs to people or businesses capturing CO<sub>2</sub>, e.g. growing trees or building futuristic Saharan solar power stations that generate power to turn CO<sub>2</sub> from the atmosphere back into carbon<ref>Cockburn, H. 2019: '''Scientists turn CO2 ‘back into coal’ in breakthrough carbon capture experiment''' ([https://www.independent.co.uk/news/science/carbon-capture-coal-electrolysis-rmit-university-melbourne-dorna-esrafilzadeh-a8798031.html Independent UK])</ref> or salt crystal<ref>Rathi, A. 2019: '''You can now pay to turn your carbon emissions to stone''' ([https://qz.com/1683044/you-can-now-pay-climeworks-to-turn-your-carbon-emissions-to-stone/ Quartz Global News])</ref> or methanol and oxygen<ref>Weston, P. 2019: '''Scientists create ‘artificial leaf’ that sucks in carbon dioxide and makes fuel''' ([https://www.independent.co.uk/news/science/artificial-leaf-carbon-dioxide-fuel-photosynthesis-climate-change-a9184031.html Independent UK])</ref>. |
||
+ | Based on past mining or drilling operations and including geological data indicating potential methane leakage from oil or coal beds, average methane leakage at any extraction site could be calculated and the appropriate carbon price added to the final bill at the carbon producer's audit by the carbon authority. |
||
− | This branch of industry is already well established as summarised by Carbon Brief in their report '''10 Ways Negative Emissions could slow Climate Change'''<ref>Pierce, R. 2020: '''Explainer: 10 ways negative emissions could slow climate change''' ([https://www.carbonbrief.org/explainer-10-ways-negative-emissions-could-slow-climate-change Carbon Brief])</ref> |
||
+ | Oil and gas wells and coal mines would be metered as described above not just for usable fossil fuels but also for leakage. Monitoring operations can be highly effective and led to the detection of the massive methane leaks from Exxon wells in Ohio<ref>Pinckard, C. 2019: '''Satellite data shows Ohio methane leak one of largest ever recorded''' ([https://www.cleveland.com/nation/2019/12/satellite-data-shows-ohio-methane-leak-one-of-largest-ever-recorded-reports-say.html Cleveland.com News Agency])</ref> and from Texas<ref>Kessel, J.M., Tabuchi, H. 2019: '''Texas Methane Super-emitters''' ([https://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2019/12/12/climate/texas-methane-super-emitters.html])</ref>. Such monitoring is also carried out by satellite. |
||
− | However as of 2020 the whole industry is not without controversy, in fact it is difficult to draw the line between this and the carbon offsetting industry. It is in these sectors that the rigour and robustness of UCC would be transformational. |
||
+ | Methane emissions from solid waste management and composting could also be done this way. Remote sensing is already used in California as part of pollution control research.<ref>IOPScience 2020: '''Using remote sensing to detect, validate, and quantify methane emissions from California solid waste operations''' ([https://iopscience.iop.org/article/10.1088/1748-9326/ab7b99])</ref> |
||
− | Not only would it promote research and investment into reforestation and carbon sequestration, but because the central carbon authority awards UCCs, it circumvents the problem of who should pay for it. The main issue would be calculating how UCC payments affect the global UCC supply and therefore the global carbon budget. |
||
+ | Methane emissions from livestock by a farmer with a dairy or beef herd would be required to pay license fees in carbon tokens per head of cattle. |
||
− | == Causes for Optimism == |
||
+ | ==Appendix 5: Preservation of natural carbon sinks and prospects for carbon drawdown== |
||
− | === Democratic Plausibility === |
||
+ | The implementation of the carbon allowances system could provide a carbon token-based income to the owners or guardians of every standing forest. The forest carbon sinks sequester about 15% of anthropogenic CO<sub>2</sub> emissions<ref>Hubau, W., Lewis, S. et al 2020: '''Asynchronous carbon sink saturation in African and Amazonian tropical forests''' ([https://www.nature.com/articles/s41586-020-2035-0 Nature])</ref>, although that rate is falling. From the opposite perspective, deforestation for economic gain would have to be monitored and audited by a global carbon authority, which would then demand the equivalent carbon tokens from the entity carrying out the deforestation. The concept applies that all carbon usage and ensuing CO<sub>2</sub> emissions in the economy must be paid for in carbon tokens. |
||
− | To a citizen considering which political manifesto to vote for, immediate threats to living standards, personal income and well-being in political manifestos generally trump more rational but long-term environmental advantages in the future. |
||
+ | The demand for biofuels would also be channelled into sustainable practices. Industrial biofuel agriculture<ref>FAO, 2008: '''FAO The State of Food and Agriculture, Part I: Biofuels: Prospects, Risks and Opportunities''' ([http://www.fao.org/docrep/011/i0100e/i0100e00.htm FAO])</ref> would need to budget for payment of carbon tokens for CO<sub>2</sub> loss due to soil degradation. Large woodchip-fired power stations would pay in carbon tokens for woodchip from forestry operations, who would be subject to audit and payment to the carbon authority for the forest clearance. Future developments with current 2020 policies could otherwise lead to unchecked deforestation.<ref>Sandbag, 2019: '''Playing With Fire: assessment of company plans to burn biomass in EU coal power stations''' ([https://sandbag.org.uk/project/playing-with-fire/ Sandbag])</ref><ref>Carbon Pulse, 2019: '''EU’s wood-fired power should face carbon price under tougher rules''' ([http://carbon-pulse.com/88900/ Carbon Pulse News Agency])</ref> |
||
− | The Australian general election of May 2019 was widely considered a climate election that was "unloseable" for the Australian Labor Party pushing a climate action agenda. The Labor Party did lose though, beaten at the polls by the incumbent Prime Minister who used every opportunity to highlight the short term financial impact that the proposed climate action would cause.<ref>Murphy, K. 2019: '''Labor lost the unlosable election''' ([https://www.theguardian.com/australia-news/2019/may/19/labor-unloseable-election-morrison-australia-plan The Guardian])</ref> |
||
+ | The continued destruction of the globally significant carbon sinks, such as the rainforests of the Amazon, Borneo and the Congo, represent a large risk to any attempts to control CO<sub>2</sub> emissions globally. The obvious culprit here is the palm oil industry with its extensive oil palm plantations, along with timber production, soya or beef farming forest clearance methods, and other drivers of deforestation by commercial interests. A global pact to implement the carbon allowances policy could create a global carbon budget for carbon tokens large enough to supply payments for carbon sinks as detailed above. |
||
− | Why would the public be interested in political leaders who adopt UCC as climate policy? |
||
+ | In parallel to the requirement for keeping forests standing, the carbon allowance policy offers a huge potential as a mechanism to pay for negative emissions. For instance, all deforested land could be reforested. As trees grow, they absorb CO<sub>2</sub> from the atmosphere. Reforestation projects can claim this weight of absorbed CO<sub>2</sub> as carbon tokens from the carbon authority. |
||
− | * At least in the short term future under the UCC framework, the introductory level of UCCs allocated on a per-capita basis would be adequate to bring about familiarity with the carbon currency without entailing an immediate change in the average person's lifestyle choices. |
||
+ | Obviously under this system, forest stewards of both intact primary forest and regrowing secondary forest would have to be subject to stringent control to the same degree as the gas/oil/coal carbon producers. |
||
− | * Only the most profligate carbon emitters would actually find themselves restricted during the first years of the framework. This tends to be a small number of wealthy people who constitute only a tiny proportion of the electorate<ref>Gössling, Stefan 2019-10-22: '''These celebrities cause 10,000 times more carbon emissions from flying than the average person''' ([https://theconversation.com/these-celebrities-cause-10-000-times-more-carbon-emissions-from-flying-than-the-average-person-123886 The Conversation])</ref>. Most would agree such people should rein in their activities. |
||
+ | The forest condition and the amount of carbon absorbed (or lost through felling) would be monitored by remote sensing in the same way that forests are currently monitored.<ref>Bae, S., Levick, S.R., Heidrich, L. et al. '''Radar vision in the mapping of forest biodiversity from space.''' ([https://www.nature.com/articles/s41467-019-12737-x Nat Commun 10, 4757 (2019) doi:10.1038/s41467-019-12737-x])</ref><ref>Almeida D. et al, 2019: '''Monitoring the structure of forest restoration plantations with a drone-lidar system''' ([https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0303243418311954 International Journal of Applied Earth Observation and Geoinformation])</ref> |
||
− | * It is probable that the progress of green technologies in the future will reduce the required UCCs in many sectors, cushioning the impact on consumers when rationing starts to cause real impact, e.g. the automobile industry |
||
+ | ==Appendix 6: More robust future for the carbon offsetting industry and the voluntary carbon markets== |
||
− | * The costs to the state and increase in taxes required to implement UCC would be small in comparison to the billions proposed for climate-related subsidies and government spending programmes. |
||
+ | The harsh reality of CO<sub>2</sub> emissions and prospects for their reduction means any realistic plan must include removing CO<sub>2</sub> from the atmosphere, or global warming will overshoot 1.5°C.<ref>Andrew, R. 2019: '''Global Carbon Budget 2019''' ([http://folk.uio.no/roberan/GCB2019.shtml CICERO Center for International Climate Research])</ref> |
||
− | The clarity and transparency of UCC - how effective it is in CO<sub>2</sub> emissions reduction and what effect it was having on the economy - would be effective right down to the individual level. This visibility would empower citizens, arguably a majority of citizens, to press their elected representatives to reduce the carbon ration supply to a greater extent as they perceive how fairly the system commands effort and forebearance across society. |
||
+ | This chart displays the Global Carbon Budget. It shows annual global CO<sub>2</sub> emissions on the Y axis in gigatonnes. In 2019 when created, the thick black curve has risen every year on the X axis. The cumulative effect of all emissions to date has resulted in a global temperature rise of 1°C above pre-industrial levels. |
||
− | === Destigmatisation of Fossil Fuels === |
||
+ | The 2015 Paris Climate Agreement between all nations targets a 1.5°C limit to global warming, with initial commitments to keep the temperature rise "well below 2°C". |
||
− | A widely-held public perception is that the extraction of fossil fuels is inherently immoral because of CO<sub>2</sub>-induced climate change and the resulting impacts. BP's corporate image for instance has suffered at the hands of public disfavour, resulting in the company losing key sponsorship deals<ref>BBC, 2019-10-02: '''RSC Ends BP Sponsorship Deal''' ([https://www.bp.com/en/global/corporate/news-and-insights/press-releases/bp-statement-in-response-to-rsc-ending-our-partnership-early.html BBC News])</ref><ref>New York Times, 2016-03-11: '''BP to End Sponsorship of Tate Museums''' ([https://www.nytimes.com/2016/03/12/business/energy-environment/bp-to-end-sponsorship-of-tate-museums.html New York Times])</ref><ref>Edinburgh Reporter, 2019-11-11: '''National Portrait Gallery Scotland to end BP Sponsorship''' ([https://www.theedinburghreporter.co.uk/2019/11/scottish-national-portrait-gallery-to-end-bp-relationship/ The Edinburgh Reporter])</ref>, being the target of divestment campaigns, and even being pressured off university campuses when trying to take part in recruitment fairs.<ref>McGibbon, A. 2020-01-16: '''Fossil Fuel Recruiters Are Being Chased Off Campuses All Over the UK''' ([https://www.vice.com/amp/en_uk/article/g5xqvx/fossil-fuel-recruiters-are-being-chased-off-campuses-all-over-the-uk Vice])</ref> |
||
+ | According to the latest climate science, to achieve a limit of 1.5°C warming, society must restrict further CO<sub>2</sub> emissions to less than 420 gigatonnes. The downward-arcing black line on the chart displays how annual emissions must decline if we adhere to the 420 gigatonne total. In other words, with current emissions at 42 gigatonnes per year, if we carried on for another 10 years, we would then need to completely stop all emissions or global warming would exceed 1.5°C. |
||
− | Commentators speak of a loss of 'social licence'<ref>Guardian, 2014: '''Defining the Social License: BP, Shell, GMO.''' ([https://www.theguardian.com/sustainable-business/2014/sep/29/social-licence-operate-shell-bp-business-leaders The Guardian])</ref> but the reality of the situation is citizens are quite prepared to ignore their own part in the process as they continue to create demand in the marketplace. Either consumers with a large carbon footprint are oblivious to the simple laws of supply and demand, or they believe the moral obligation lies with the government to resolve all CO<sub>2</sub> emissions-related problems, but they also refuse to vote for such action. |
||
+ | . |
||
− | However, when citizens go to pay for products or services using UCCs, they have in their hands the undeniable evidence that their actions result in CO<sub>2</sub> emissions. The only other option is to 'retire' those UCCs. A new social contract under UCC would re-legitimise the extraction of fossil fuels and recreate the social license, bearing in mind the context of a steadily reducing carbon ration supply. |
||
+ | https://folk.uio.no/roberan/t/i/mitigation_curves_1.5C_191203.png |
||
− | This change in attitude is likely to feed into the more general climate debate to reduce the polarisation and lack of broad political agreement. Because the ethics of the capitalist market economy almost by definition allow business-as-usual, increasing numbers of citizens believe that the supply of fossil fuels is morally wrong. With a carbon rationing system in place, the ethics of the market place can be brought back more in line with society's general moral standards regarding continuation of our way of life, impacts of our actions on people in other parts of the world and so on. |
||
+ | As the chart text states, such sudden emissions reduction is practically impossible. The only way to keep the total extra anthropogenic CO<sub>2</sub> added to the atmosphere below 420 Gigatonnes from 2020 is to pull CO<sub>2</sub> out of the atmosphere - "negative emissions", in the appropriate huge quantities. |
||
− | === Business, Entrepreneurial and Industrial Attraction === |
||
− | |||
− | Business ultimately plays by a set of rules defined in law and is typically only concerned only with profit and loss generated by its actions within that context. The personal environmental motivations of directors and managers may often be expressed in their business models but many such business practices can be summarily swept aside by a change of leadership. |
||
− | |||
− | For business, UCC is relatively basic. It makes going green part of the rules. |
||
− | |||
− | While carbon pricing mechanisms and carbon taxes in general can integrate some 'environmental information' via price discovery in the market, UCC actually creates a new parallel market. |
||
− | |||
− | Due to the relative simplicity of carbon rationing, it brings more dependability and certainty. Carbon pricing policies usually have highly inconsistent track records. Being smaller, more regional and more targetted than UCC, they are highly prone to uncertainties of political intervention in a way that a blanket, comprehensive framework like UCC would not be. |
||
− | |||
− | Carbon pricing policies rely on inclusions and exclusions on a sector by sector basis and variation in carbon accounting practices dependent on national law. Carbon rationing on the other hand would provide comprehensive coverage of the economy and a comparatively small set of economic indicators, influences and unknowns. This would provide the backdrop for a reliable investment framework that gives a clear pathway for innovation towards carbon neutrality. |
||
− | |||
− | Businesses also complain that any attempts to go carbon-neutral result in a loss of competitiveness and market share as their customers switch to cheaper imported high-carbon alternatives. In a unilateral implementation, since UCC imposes the UCCs on imports at customs, the playing field is level and it prevents free-riders. |
||
− | |||
− | Other business problems also arise with a piecemeal approach to carbon policy. Shipping illustrates a typical problem businesses face. The International Maritime Organisation brokered a international agreement that shipping fuel must be used more efficiently by 2020, but despite 20 years preparation, it is on the verge of failure because of disagreement over who bears responsibility in the industry.<ref>Financial Times, 2019-11-14: '''What we can learn from the 2020 shipping fuel switch''' ([https://www.ft.com/content/4c3e5fdc-0601-11ea-a984-fbbacad9e7dd Financial Times])</ref> |
||
− | |||
− | === Starting Nationally, Thinking Globally === |
||
− | |||
− | UCC can be implemented unilaterally by any nation, not requiring unanimous approval from hundreds of nations. |
||
− | |||
− | A nation's national borders and customs agency would act as proxy for importers of foreign goods and services, collecting the required UCCs on imported goods from the buyers. |
||
− | |||
− | The biggest challenge would be to avoid international legal disputes over any perceived violation of pre-existing trade agreements because of the introduction of rationing controls on the imported goods. |
||
− | |||
− | Other nations could join with the first nation at any point to form a larger trading block. |
||
− | |||
− | === United Nations === |
||
− | |||
− | The United Nations approached climate action from a top-down perspective until 2009 at the COP15 in Copenhagen, Denmark. Since then a bottom-up or 'pledge-and-review' framework has been the goal. Whatever the reasons given for this, the bottom-up approach is obviously easier if seeking a unanimous global agreement from the UNFCCC conventions. The bottom-up approach is what resulted in the 2015 Paris Agreement. |
||
− | |||
− | The Paris Agreement was passed unanimously. That in itself was a feat of international diplomacy. However the Nationally Determined Contributions are not enforceable.<ref>ECIU 2019: '''The Paris Agreement''' |
||
− | ([https://eciu.net/briefings/international-perspectives/the-paris-climate-agreement Energy & Climate Intelligence Unit Briefings])</ref> The 1.5°C limit to global warming imagined in the agreement is looking increasingly unachievable. The Climate Action Tracker<ref>Climate Action Tracker, 2019: '''USA Pledges and Targets critically insufficient''' ([https://climateactiontracker.org/countries/usa/pledges-and-targets Climate Action Tracker])</ref> currently shows most monitored countries have not made sufficient commitments in their NDCs to be compatible with the agreement. |
||
− | |||
− | Whether the UNFCCC process turns back towards a top-down approach, or finds a middle road,<ref>Pickering, John 2015: '''Top-down proposals for sharing the global climate policy effort fairly: lost in translation in a bottom-up world?''' ([http://www.governanceinstitute.edu.au/magma/media/upload/ckeditor/files/Top-down%20vs%20bottom-up%20-%20working%20paper%20version%201.pdf Governance Inst Australia]) '''PDF'''</ref>, by the unilateral implementation of UCC and then the building of a UCC-based trading block, a unanimous vote at the UN is not a necessity. |
||
− | |||
− | The ideal solution to provide an international basis for carbon ration allocation would be the Global Commons Initiative Contraction and Convergence Framework. <ref>Meyer, A. 1992: '''GCI Contraction and Convergence Framework''' ([http://www.gci.org.uk/ GCI.org.uk])</ref> This is the essence of decades of international climate diplomacy, as used by UNFCCC, UK Government, the Brazilian, Russian, Indian, and Chinese delegations and as a basis for proposals by various organisations and political parties ever since.<ref>Wikipedia 2019: '''Contraction and Convergence''' ([https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Contraction_and_Convergence Wikipedia])</ref> |
||
− | |||
− | [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Contraction_and_Convergence https://upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/commons/2/22/Web_C%26C.png] |
||
− | |||
− | The chart above shows at the top, the annual rates of carbon emissions allocated per capita per country, and below, in total per country (from 2000). |
||
− | |||
− | It illustrates how national allocations can be negotiated to the satisfaction of all countries by commencing at different per capita levels and then converging at an agreed point before contracting. |
||
+ | Using its ability to take carbon tokens from its national carbon budget as described above, the central carbon bank would promote “negative emissions” by awarding tokens to people or businesses capturing CO<sub>2</sub>, e.g. growing trees or building futuristic Saharan solar power stations that generate power to turn CO<sub>2</sub> from the atmosphere back into carbon<ref>Cockburn, H. 2019: '''Scientists turn CO2 ‘back into coal’ in breakthrough carbon capture experiment''' ([https://www.independent.co.uk/news/science/carbon-capture-coal-electrolysis-rmit-university-melbourne-dorna-esrafilzadeh-a8798031.html Independent UK])</ref> or salt crystal<ref>Rathi, A. 2019: '''You can now pay to turn your carbon emissions to stone''' ([https://qz.com/1683044/you-can-now-pay-climeworks-to-turn-your-carbon-emissions-to-stone/ Quartz Global News])</ref> or methanol and oxygen<ref>Weston, P. 2019: '''Scientists create ‘artificial leaf’ that sucks in carbon dioxide and makes fuel''' ([https://www.independent.co.uk/news/science/artificial-leaf-carbon-dioxide-fuel-photosynthesis-climate-change-a9184031.html Independent UK])</ref>. This branch of industry is no longer in its infancy as summarised by Carbon Brief in their report "10 Ways Negative Emissions could slow Climate Change"<ref>Pierce, R. 2020: '''Explainer: 10 ways negative emissions could slow climate change''' ([https://www.carbonbrief.org/explainer-10-ways-negative-emissions-could-slow-climate-change Carbon Brief])</ref> but requires the investment to scale up. |
||
− | == Conclusion == |
||
+ | However as of 2020 the whole industry is not without controversy in the way that its CO<sub>2</sub> drawdown is certified. In fact it is difficult to draw the line between this and the carbon offsetting industry. It is in these sectors that the rigour and robustness in validation and payments by a centralised carbon authority would be transformational. |
||
− | Universal Carbon Credits as a Carbon Currency (or Total Carbon Rationing) is a whole supply chain carbon rationing policy that covers individuals as well as companies, industries and government. While implementation would require substantial changes, there are strong reasons to believe it would induce an exponential increase in the rate of national decarbonisation and would be more likely to succeed that any other climate policy. |
||
+ | Not only would it promote research and investment into reforestation and carbon sequestration, but because the central carbon authority awards tokens from the central carbon budget, it circumvents the problem of who should pay for it. The main issue would be monitoring land use and other carbon drawdown mechanisms, and administering claims. |
||
− | Supply-side control of fossil fuel extraction rates is the sole policy that can limit carbon supply and guarantee decarbonisation targets. The UCC system once in place would bring individual engagement and increases in carbon literacy from citizens. It would create various advantages in transparency, predictability, efficiency, innovation and separation of concerns for business. As well as the direct personal impact and the effect of this mechanism on business, the implementation of UCC would have further advantages covering political impacts, natural resources, international trade, the negative emissions and voluntary carbon market and financial systems in general as economies seek to accelerate decarbonisation. |
||
− | == References |
+ | == References== |
<references /> |
<references /> |
Latest revision as of 22:45, 13 May 2022
The Case for Change
Climate science provides the quantity of CO2 emissions allowable under various emissions scenarios. The dramatic crossroads for humanity as outlined by the United Nations Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change's 2022 report offers two ways forward: without concerted, rapid and unprecedented efforts to reduce CO2 emissions, the effects of climate change will likely cause massive loss of life, property, and nature. Doing nothing but rely on technological developments to bring about the obsolescence of fossil fuels is a policy that forecasting scenarios show cannot keep global warming below 3.0°C. This will bring global economic recessions along with damage and adaptation costs in the order of trillions of US dollars. This may induce governments to shut down the fossil fuel industry in short order to limit further losses, regardless of the drastic, disorganised impact on the economy.
The Paris Agreement was passed unanimously. That in itself was a feat of international diplomacy. However the Nationally Determined Contributions are not enforceable[1]. The 1.5°C limit to global warming imagined in the agreement is looking increasingly unachievable. The Climate Action Tracker[2] currently shows most monitored countries have not made sufficient commitments in their NDCs to be compatible with the agreement.
The Policy Concept
Government
The UK Committee on Climate Change produced an extensive and wide-ranging document[3] outlining a policy path to achieve net zero CO2 emissions by 2050 and immediately realised 2 problems: were their recommendations plausible[4] and are they even the best choice?[5]
Already academic policy analysts predict that governments will be unable to rise to the challenge without fundamental organisational restructuring[6]. This policy would allow decision-makers to focus on how much carbon emissions to allow, rather than how to implement those emissions cuts.
Individuals
The concept of a carbon allowance is similar to rationing, which is categorised by economists as a fundamentally progressive fiscal policy - in other words, it is fair. Studies looking at rationing in the 1940s and 1950s show this. The quantity of carbon tokens in the allowance should be allocated on a per capita basis to citizens.
In this system, the carbon allowance would be paid regularly via a personal carbon account. Children and teenagers would receive a percentage of the adult quota. Governments would withhold a certain percentage of citizens' allowance like a tax, to pay the carbon costs of running public services.
To reduce CO2 emissions to zero, the first allowance period would begin by allocating enough carbon tokens to cover society’s existing emissions. At the individual level, this would only impact those with an above-average carbon footprint. The allocation would then be steadily reduced over time. Reduction might need to be stepped up in circumstances of accelerating climatic instability, or the allowance might temporarily increase to stave off exceptional economic damage, but always with the additional guarantee that due to supply restrictions, reduction targets will be met.
To prevent anybody being unfairly affected by the system, the government would hold back a percentage of everybody’s carbon allowance. This can be used to supplement those in extra need of carbon tokens through no fault of their own.
If introduced, every citizen and every business would have to become adept at handling their carbon tokens in the same way as money. it allows individual citizens to make their own decisions on where to make savings. Few of us would be forced to cut down in all areas of consumption, most could make carbon savings where convenient for our lifestyle. No one would be imposing decisions on our behalf.
Business
Business ultimately plays by a set of rules defined in law and is typically only concerned only with profit and loss generated by its actions within that context. For business, UCC is relatively basic. It makes going green part of the rules.
Under the system, businesses would charge customers carbon tokens, as well as money, for all products and services, which it would carefully manage to cover all of its own carbon expenditure.
Every product or service that is bought and sold would be subject to the system: every vendor, every merchant, every shopkeeper, every business person who sells anything must put the carbon price on their product or service next to the cash price, even if it is truly a zero emissions product. It provides a practical solution for difficult industry sectors like aviation, shipping, inbuilt or imported emissions, public services or the military.
The businesses use their carbon token income to pay for the goods and services they use in their supply chain. This method of pricing the carbon in everything in the supply chain goes back through the supply chain until the end source is reached, with the carbon producers (the oil/gas/coal extraction companies).
Carbon tokens would flow via every business transaction through the supply chain from the end-carbon-consumer (citizen) to the original carbon producer. So they would flow through the economy as a second parallel currency, affecting every product or service which exists and is for sale, from televisions to train tickets, and requiring two figures on the price tag – a price in local currency ($, £, €, ¥ etc) and a carbon price in tokens.
From the technological perspective, business would be compelled to introduce accounting software to account for carbon token income and expenditure. Key to the system and how it generates the carbon price for products and services is the rule that businesses, commerce and industry do not receive any carbon tokens as an allowance: the citizens create the market for the products and services, and their willingness or not to pay any given carbon price is the ultimate feedback in the process.
With modern supply chains, a product or service’s carbon price is kept up to date by the businesses involved, from manufacture right through packaging, freight, and storage. The final carbon price to the end consumer is simply the accumulation of carbon token costs that were added on and demanded in payment at each step in the supply chain. This establishes a direct link between the volume of carbon tokens allocated by the central carbon authority and the final CO2 emissions produced in the economy in any one period.
One significant advantage of carbon tokens is the continual dynamic update of the UCC price charged for each product or service as business becomes more carbon-neutral. The price tag would display exactly how much CO2 in total was generated in the manufacture and supply of the product. It would be reduced by the vendors to reflect environmental improvements as they take place. This real-time ‘green flag’ lends a dynamism to the decarbonisation process on a scale impossible to achieve by any bureaucratic mandates or carbon tax scheme.
Such a scheme would immediately push businesses to seek out the lowest emission options in their supply chain, so that their offerings have the lowest carbon price they can manage and the best chances against the competition. Products or services which currently sell at a high price due to their low CO2 emissions, high sustainability or eco-friendliness will become much more attractive due to their low carbon price.
Fossil Fuel Industry
The other key actors in the system are the carbon producers - the oil, gas and coal suppliers. Supply-side control of fossil fuel extraction rates is the sole policy that directly limits carbon supply and guarantees decarbonisation.
Every gas or oil well and coal mine operation would be subject to upstream metering by the carbon authority to measure the quantity of fossil fuels extracted, for audit and payment of carbon token income.
The carbon producers would charge carbon tokens on their fossil fuel sales, weight for weight in tonnes, kilos and grammes of carbon, which is how the carbon tokens are denominated. The corporate accounts would be subject to audit by this central carbon authority. All carbon extracted – gas, oil, coal – would require surrender of the equivalent carbon tokens.
Compliance in the whole carbon currency system would take place at the carbon producers, who become the lynchpin for policing of fossil fuel extraction and thus CO2 emissions. It is the extraction of fossil fuels that is monitored and audited rather than their sale, because the fossil fuel producers in many cases use their own products to power their operations, or even allow their escape, e.g. methane leaks or flaring.
Downstream companies in the petrochemical industry and beyond in wider industry which do not extract fossil fuels would, by definition of the system, not be subject to metering or payment of carbon tokens to the carbon authority.
The Carbon Market
The ability to purchase extra carbon tokens from citizens or businesses would minimise problems when adaptation is slow or insufficient for whatever reason.
Wealthy citizens could buy extra carbon tokens to subsidise their carbon-heavy choices, but only what other people are selling, and that will decrease regularly as the carbon allowances are steadily reduced. Such a market for tokens is not a loophole that some observers might think prevents actual CO2 emissions reduction from taking place, because firstly, not allowing the sale of tokens could encourage people who would otherwise be carbon-conscious to use up all their un-tradeable allowance on cheap high-carbon products. Secondly, the market for buying and selling carbon tokens represents a safety mechanism in the system that prevents people or businesses falling off a carbon “cliff edge” if they run out of tokens.
Implementation
The carbon allowance policy can be implemented unilaterally by any nation, not requiring unanimous approval from hundreds of nations at the United Nations.
The roll-out could be implemented by central banks using digital currency frameworks – unilaterally by nation or within trading blocs by the creation of carbon borders with non-implementing trading partners, where customs authorities act as proxy and impose the carbon price on the domestic importers at the border. It could also be negotiated multilaterally with agreements on national carbon allowances via the existing UNFCCC-compliant GCI Contraction and Convergence treaty model.
The Central Carbon Authority
A central carbon authority would be established, similar in function to a central bank, to administer monetary control of the carbon currency. It would oversee the allocation of carbon allowances to citizens.
It would run the carbon market where citizens and business come to sell surplus tokens or obtain extra requirement.
It would also process the payment, audit and verification of carbon tokens from the carbon producers.
Central banks across the globe are already putting in place the framework for an international digital reserve currency. This could be duplicated for the purposes of carbon allowances.
Carbon tokens would not expire, so the carbon authority would also monitor, manage and report on the carbon currency supply - the quantity of carbon tokens held by citizens and businesses. This information would feed back into the decision-making process for calculating the optimal quantity of tokens to allocate for each period.
The carbon authority would also mandate a negative interest rate on all carbon accounts to discourage stockpiling.
National Implementation
Any nation or trading bloc could immediately implement the policy, where the customs authority sets up a proxy at the trading border to impose the carbon price required on incoming goods (which is paid by the importer). A nation's national borders and customs agency would act as proxy for importers of foreign goods and services, collecting the required carbon tokens on imported goods from the buyers.
Other nations could join with the first nation at any point to form a larger trading block.
International Implementation
The ultimate goal and the most effective situation would be the implementation of the policy across the global economy. This would provide society with the best chances of meeting the growing challenges that climate change represents.
One solution to provide an international basis for carbon allocation would be the Global Commons Initiative's Contraction and Convergence Framework[7]. This is the essence of decades of international climate diplomacy, as used by UNFCCC, UK Government, the Brazilian, Russian, Indian, and Chinese delegations and as a basis for proposals by various organisations and political parties ever since[8].
On an international scale ultimately all citizens from all nations would receive the same individual allowance of carbon tokens. This would start differently for different countries yet end up the same by global agreement, using a UN-brokered convention based on the Contraction and Convergence system.
The chart below shows, at the top, the annual rates of carbon emissions allocated (tonnes carbon per capita per country), and below, in gigatonnes of carbon total per country (from 2000).
It illustrates how national allocations can be negotiated to the satisfaction of all countries by commencing at different per capita levels and then converging at an agreed point before contracting.
Cost of Implementation
Compared to the “free” option of doing nothing or “business as usual”, the carbon allowance policy has a large, up-front cost with manageable, contained, on-going running costs similar to VAT or German MwSt.
Compared to carbon tax policies, the large up-front cost comes as business, government and citizens prepare for its introduction. Studies in 2008 in the UK and more recent studies on projects such a road traffic in Kenya and local transport in Finland show that costs are not prohibitive.
But taxes, trading schemes, legislative bans or subsidy programs have significant running costs to maintain the level of carbon policymaking that rationing would make redundant:
- establishing what citizens and industry have to stop doing
- democratically agreeing on it
- legislating for it
- implementing the laws
- monitoring the effects
- constantly strengthening the laws in the face of political opposition
And all this would be repeated for each individual policy for every nation in the world.
So the carbon tax alternatives are initially cheaper, but they have higher legislative costs as governments manage decarbonisation, legislating year after year to keep up with economic and technological developments and unforeseen issues. The longer it lasts, the more likely it is that the carbon allowance policy turns out cheaper.
The costs to the state and increase in taxes required to implement the system would be small in comparison to the billions proposed for climate-related subsidies and government spending programmes.
Advantages
No requirement for carbon labelling laws: the carbon price of every item creates itself via cumulative addition up the supply chain. The system results in a dynamic, responsive carbon price for everything with no requirement for government to research and label everything with a fixed, statutory carbon price.
Transparency in commerce: people and green businesses currently base their consumer choices on information that is often not on the label, is incomplete, or worse, is misleading or purposefully suppressed. Very few things have the same carbon transparency as buying a tank of fuel to drive somewhere. There are unexpected inputs, hidden subsidies and incalculable interactions which make some things' actual carbon footprint differ radically from the expected. This system's cumulative supply chain carbon price irons out these issues and distributes the effort of setting the carbon price to the place where it is most easily done - by the people creating the product or delivering the service.
Transparency in the fossil fuel industry: the metering of fossil fuel extraction at source gives a direct measure of the carbon entering the economy and the CO2 emissions produced. Progress would be clear to all. The significance of government or central carbon bank decision-making within the system would also be readily understood.
Direct control over fossil fuel supply: because there is a one-to-one relationship between carbon tokens and the all the oil, gas or coal that fossil fuel producers are permitted to extract from the ground, the government's control over how much fossil fuel is produced and how much CO2 is emitted is direct, unlike the situation with carbon tax, where the impact on CO2 emissions is dependent on the economy's reaction to the carbon tax.
Driver of green innovation: progress towards a zero emissions economy in any circumstances will only occur at a fast enough pace if inventiveness and innovation can be harnessed to create new methods and processes. Because every individual will develop a solid carbon literacy through their everyday use of their own personal carbon account, people will bring this into their work and drive the economy's adaptation to the system from the inside out. Compare this with the impact of carbon taxes: worldwide implementation of carbon taxes in 2020 covered only 16% of the economy, leaving the "carbon price gap" standing at 84%[9]. The coverage of the proposed carbon currency system would be practically 100%. So the inherent "price signal" for carbon under the carbon currency system would be 5 times stronger than from carbon taxes as it stands. The stronger impact would accelerate business adaptation and innovation.
Cross-border trade: any nation or trading bloc using this system instructs its customs authority to set up a proxy at the border to impose an estimated carbon price on incoming goods, which is paid by the importer.
Facilitation and promotion of carbon drawdown: the government has a national budget for carbon allowances which it uses to allocate every citizen's allowance. It can pay in carbon tokens from this budget for atmospheric CO2 removal, e.g. in soils via sustainable farming practices, rewilding, the protection of ocean carbon sinks or any kind of mechanical carbon drawdown. Recipients would be able to sell the carbon tokens they earn at the going rate. The higher the carbon token price, the more it would promote carbon drawdown.
Introduction of system is no cause for alarm: the introductory level of carbon tokens allocated for the personal allowance would be adequate to bring about familiarity with the carbon currency without entailing an immediate change in the average person's lifestyle choices. Only the most profligate carbon emitters would actually find themselves restricted during the first years of the system's implementation. This tends to be a small number of wealthy people who constitute only a tiny proportion of the electorate. Most would agree such people should rein in their carbon-intensive activities.
Long term impacts ameliorated by advances in technology: it is probable that the progress of green technologies in the future will reduce the required carbon tokens in many sectors, cushioning the impact on consumers when allowance reductions start to cause real impact
Comparison with other approaches
Carbon tax is always criticised for its unfairness because those with lower incomes generally end up paying proportionately more of their income for it, but carbon allowances are allocated equally per capita, and allow those on low incomes who have on average smaller carbon footprints to profit from selling their excess.
The worldwide implementation of carbon taxes and ETS schemes in 2020 covered only 16% of the economy, leaving the "carbon price gap" standing at 84%[9]. The coverage of the proposed carbon currency system would be practically 100%. So the inherent "price signal" for carbon under the carbon currency system would be 5 times stronger than from carbon taxes as it stands. The stronger impact would accelerate business adaptation and innovation.
It is also quite complex and difficult to construct a carbon pricing system and then to implement it using policies that can only implement partial coverage. Multiple issues occur, especially on a political level e.g. in British Columbia, Canada[10][11], in the EU[12].
Other attempts to control society's widespread and deeply rooted CO2 emissions via the creation of a multitude of decarbonisation mandates in government have also not had the desired effect. The problem with regulation-based policies is the extended time horizons associated with such policies. The EU in 2020 displayed a particularly egregious example of this. The implementation of the 'EU Green New Deal' will only take force 10 years down the line in 2030 and it does not allow for greater ambition until 2035.[13]
The carbon allowances policy has an advantage over every other kind of carbon pricing policy, because other policies attempt to guess the “right” price for carbon, without knowing in advance how great its impact will be, because they are not comprehensively applied to all sources of CO2 emissions and they suffer from variations in the sensitivity of supply and demand. We roughly know the quantity of CO2 emissions we can allow for various global warming scenarios, so it is more robust approach to use that figure to set a per capita allowance.
Many climate policy discussions would be solved by this policy's broad coverage. It's simpler, more efficient and more direct to control the quantity of carbon entering the economy than the carbon price, which is fundamentally a difficult policy making exercise, prone to failure and political intervention. They rely on inclusions and exclusions on a sector by sector basis and variation in carbon accounting practices dependent on national law. Carbon allowances on the other hand would provide comprehensive coverage of the economy and a comparatively small set of economic indicators, influences and unknowns. This would provide the backdrop for a reliable investment framework that gives a clear pathway for innovation towards carbon neutrality.
Shipping illustrates a typical problem businesses face. The International Maritime Organisation brokered a international agreement that shipping fuel must be used more efficiently by 2020, but despite 20 years preparation, it is on the verge of failure because of disagreement over who bears responsibility in the industry[14]. The carbon allowances policy would enable an individual nation to include shipping under its umbrella via the customs proxy mechanism described above to solve international responsibility issue, and the fuel costs would carry the carbon costs, solving the ownership issue.
Appendix 1: Also Known As
The system's original name “Total Carbon Rationing” contains the word “Total” because every product or service that is bought and sold is subject to the system: every vendor, every merchant, every shopkeeper, every business person who sells anything must put the carbon price on their product or service next to the usual price, even if it is truly a zero emissions product.
It was later given the title "Universal Carbon Credits".
In 2022, following professional advice, we developed a communications strategy that called for simpler vocabulary: hence it became the "carbon currency based on carbon allowances".
Appendix 2: Central carbon authority
By setting a CO2 emissions reduction goal and distributing the carbon allowances that achieve this reduction, a nation has a policy tool that acts as an economic tuning mechanism allowing the rate of CO2 emissions reduction to be balanced against any negative impacts it causes. The goal should be to keep reduction rates at the highest economically feasible level. Faced with deteriorating climatic conditions or sea level changes for example, or unexpected synergies appearing with the growth of the low carbon economy, adjusting the size of the next carbon allowances budget gives a straightforward lever to soft-pedal or step up decarbonisation.
Appendix 3: Practical example of carbon token usage in commerce
For simplicity’s sake, imagine that the UK has implemented the policy unilaterally. The UK carbon authority will then work in tandem with the customs authorities to impose the carbon token price on all goods and services coming in from other countries. Now say you want to buy a television, for instance. How do the carbon tokens fit into the commercial process?
- The UK carbon authority has allocated all citizens an equal amount of carbon tokens, reflecting absolute tonnes and kilos of carbon. When you choose a TV in a retail outlet, the price tag will show both the price in sterling and the price in tokens, and in all the preceding business transactions leading to the TV arriving in the shop, there will have been these joint costs – money and tokens.
- The TV is made from component parts, some originating in the UK, others from abroad. The plastic casing, in this example, was made in the UK so already has incurred a carbon cost which the case-maker will need to recoup when the TV manufacturer buys it. Making the case used a lot of energy and requires plastic, so the case manufacturer worked out the carbon cost in tokens by adding (a) the tokens paid to the energy provider, and (b) the tokens paid for the petrochemicals to make the plastic.
- The energy provider might be using gas or coal, wind or nuclear, but let’s say it’s North Sea gas from BP, so the energy provider had to pay BP the tokens per tonne of gas bought. BP is one end of this production chain, and will be paying the UK carbon authority carbon tokens representing a tonne of carbon for every tonne of carbon in the gas it pumps out of the North Sea.
- Other components of this TV have been imported from outside the UK, from countries not yet in the system – the flat screen, for example, has come from China. The UK customs officer has an estimate of how much carbon was emitted in the making of the flat screen, and levies this amount at the border. Delivery to the TV manufacturer only occurs on payment of the required tokens to the UK customs authority.
- The TV manufacturing business has now bought the component parts, paying the required tokens, and makes the television, using more energy.
- The final calculation for the TV manufacturer is: carbon price = ( tokens needed for parts + tokens paid for energy )
- All tokens expended must be recouped from its customer, the retailer.
- Now the retailer purchases the television from the manufacturer, paying the tokens required, and prices it for sale, slightly increasing the tokens demanded of the final customer because it has to keep its shop warm in winter, and pay to transport the televisions.
- Finally you, the customer, go to the retailer and choose the television, gauging the price as usual and also the carbon price in tokens, and paying both money and tokens in one transaction.
- So the four-step cumulative carbon price in tokens for the TV looks like this:
- A for the energy costs, in tokens, for North Sea gas extracted by BP, paid first by the energy provider and then after the energy is generated, by the plastic case manufacturer
- plus B for the added carbon costs of the imported screen and other component parts, paid for by the TV manufacturer
- plus C for the energy costs of production, added by the TV manufacturer
- and finally D for the extra energy costs of storage and transport added by the retailer.
- All four costs are eventually met by the customer’s token purchase price.
- Passing on the cost of carbon priced in tokens in this way makes the primary carbon producers (in this case BP) the ultimate recipients of tokens, and the key audit point – regular audits will be carried out by the carbon authority to assure compliance between the quantity of fossil fuels extracted from the ground and the tokens that they procure via their sales of those fuels.
Appendix 4: Methane control under the carbon allowances system
CH4 is a highly potent greenhouse gas, 28 times greater than CO2 over 100 years (or 84x over 20)[15]. Methane leakages from fossil fuel extraction, mining for minerals such as copper[16], farming of ruminant mammals, solid waste management and several other activities are problematic areas for emissions control policies due to the significant quantities of non-CO2 greenhouse gases that are emitted. In most cases though they are already well-regulated industries, so lending themselves to coverage by the carbon allowances system. This can be done by licensing the operation to emit greenhouse gases against purchase of a license, priced in carbon tokens according to the quantity to be emitted, calculated as C02e (CO2 equivalent).
Based on past mining or drilling operations and including geological data indicating potential methane leakage from oil or coal beds, average methane leakage at any extraction site could be calculated and the appropriate carbon price added to the final bill at the carbon producer's audit by the carbon authority.
Oil and gas wells and coal mines would be metered as described above not just for usable fossil fuels but also for leakage. Monitoring operations can be highly effective and led to the detection of the massive methane leaks from Exxon wells in Ohio[17] and from Texas[18]. Such monitoring is also carried out by satellite.
Methane emissions from solid waste management and composting could also be done this way. Remote sensing is already used in California as part of pollution control research.[19]
Methane emissions from livestock by a farmer with a dairy or beef herd would be required to pay license fees in carbon tokens per head of cattle.
Appendix 5: Preservation of natural carbon sinks and prospects for carbon drawdown
The implementation of the carbon allowances system could provide a carbon token-based income to the owners or guardians of every standing forest. The forest carbon sinks sequester about 15% of anthropogenic CO2 emissions[20], although that rate is falling. From the opposite perspective, deforestation for economic gain would have to be monitored and audited by a global carbon authority, which would then demand the equivalent carbon tokens from the entity carrying out the deforestation. The concept applies that all carbon usage and ensuing CO2 emissions in the economy must be paid for in carbon tokens.
The demand for biofuels would also be channelled into sustainable practices. Industrial biofuel agriculture[21] would need to budget for payment of carbon tokens for CO2 loss due to soil degradation. Large woodchip-fired power stations would pay in carbon tokens for woodchip from forestry operations, who would be subject to audit and payment to the carbon authority for the forest clearance. Future developments with current 2020 policies could otherwise lead to unchecked deforestation.[22][23]
The continued destruction of the globally significant carbon sinks, such as the rainforests of the Amazon, Borneo and the Congo, represent a large risk to any attempts to control CO2 emissions globally. The obvious culprit here is the palm oil industry with its extensive oil palm plantations, along with timber production, soya or beef farming forest clearance methods, and other drivers of deforestation by commercial interests. A global pact to implement the carbon allowances policy could create a global carbon budget for carbon tokens large enough to supply payments for carbon sinks as detailed above.
In parallel to the requirement for keeping forests standing, the carbon allowance policy offers a huge potential as a mechanism to pay for negative emissions. For instance, all deforested land could be reforested. As trees grow, they absorb CO2 from the atmosphere. Reforestation projects can claim this weight of absorbed CO2 as carbon tokens from the carbon authority.
Obviously under this system, forest stewards of both intact primary forest and regrowing secondary forest would have to be subject to stringent control to the same degree as the gas/oil/coal carbon producers.
The forest condition and the amount of carbon absorbed (or lost through felling) would be monitored by remote sensing in the same way that forests are currently monitored.[24][25]
Appendix 6: More robust future for the carbon offsetting industry and the voluntary carbon markets
The harsh reality of CO2 emissions and prospects for their reduction means any realistic plan must include removing CO2 from the atmosphere, or global warming will overshoot 1.5°C.[26]
This chart displays the Global Carbon Budget. It shows annual global CO2 emissions on the Y axis in gigatonnes. In 2019 when created, the thick black curve has risen every year on the X axis. The cumulative effect of all emissions to date has resulted in a global temperature rise of 1°C above pre-industrial levels.
The 2015 Paris Climate Agreement between all nations targets a 1.5°C limit to global warming, with initial commitments to keep the temperature rise "well below 2°C".
According to the latest climate science, to achieve a limit of 1.5°C warming, society must restrict further CO2 emissions to less than 420 gigatonnes. The downward-arcing black line on the chart displays how annual emissions must decline if we adhere to the 420 gigatonne total. In other words, with current emissions at 42 gigatonnes per year, if we carried on for another 10 years, we would then need to completely stop all emissions or global warming would exceed 1.5°C.
.
As the chart text states, such sudden emissions reduction is practically impossible. The only way to keep the total extra anthropogenic CO2 added to the atmosphere below 420 Gigatonnes from 2020 is to pull CO2 out of the atmosphere - "negative emissions", in the appropriate huge quantities.
Using its ability to take carbon tokens from its national carbon budget as described above, the central carbon bank would promote “negative emissions” by awarding tokens to people or businesses capturing CO2, e.g. growing trees or building futuristic Saharan solar power stations that generate power to turn CO2 from the atmosphere back into carbon[27] or salt crystal[28] or methanol and oxygen[29]. This branch of industry is no longer in its infancy as summarised by Carbon Brief in their report "10 Ways Negative Emissions could slow Climate Change"[30] but requires the investment to scale up.
However as of 2020 the whole industry is not without controversy in the way that its CO2 drawdown is certified. In fact it is difficult to draw the line between this and the carbon offsetting industry. It is in these sectors that the rigour and robustness in validation and payments by a centralised carbon authority would be transformational.
Not only would it promote research and investment into reforestation and carbon sequestration, but because the central carbon authority awards tokens from the central carbon budget, it circumvents the problem of who should pay for it. The main issue would be monitoring land use and other carbon drawdown mechanisms, and administering claims.
References
- ↑ ECIU 2019: The Paris Agreement (Energy & Climate Intelligence Unit Briefings)
- ↑ Climate Action Tracker, 2019: USA Pledges and Targets critically insufficient (Climate Action Tracker)
- ↑ UK Committee on Climate Change: Net Zero 2050 Strategy UKCCC (2019)
- ↑ UK Parliament Commons Select Committee 2019: Government’s target for ‘net-zero’ by 2050 undeliverable unless clean growth policies introduced (UK Parliament)
- ↑ Workman, M. et al: Decision making in contexts of deep uncertainty - An alternative approach for long-term climate policy Science Direct (2019)
- ↑ UK Government: UK Government’s target for ‘net-zero’ by 2050 undeliverable unless clean growth policies introduced. UK Government Science and Technology Committee 2020
- ↑ Meyer, A.: GCI Contraction and Convergence Framework GCI.org.uk (1992)
- ↑ Wikipedia: Contraction and Convergence Wikipedia (2019)
- ↑ 9.0 9.1 World Bank 2020: State and Trends of Carbon Pricing 2020 (World Bank, Washington DC)
- ↑ Corkall, V., Gass, P. 2019: Locked In and Losing Out: British Columbia’s fossil fuel subsidies (IISD)
- ↑ Campbell, K. 2019: Amid calls for stronger carbon levy, P.E.I. PCs vow to keep cutting gas taxes (CBC News)
- ↑ Just, S. 2017: The carbon price thaw: Post freeze future of GB carbon price (Aurora Energy Research)
- ↑ Abnett, K.: Environment groups say EU's planned climate law means a lost decade Reuters (2020)
- ↑ Financial Times, 2019-11-14: What we can learn from the 2020 shipping fuel switch (Financial Times)
- ↑ US EPA: Understanding Global Warming Potentials (United States Environmental Protection Agency)
- ↑ Azadi, M. et al 2020: Transparency on greenhouse gas emissions from mining to enable climate change mitigation (Nature Geoscience)
- ↑ Pinckard, C. 2019: Satellite data shows Ohio methane leak one of largest ever recorded (Cleveland.com News Agency)
- ↑ Kessel, J.M., Tabuchi, H. 2019: Texas Methane Super-emitters ([1])
- ↑ IOPScience 2020: Using remote sensing to detect, validate, and quantify methane emissions from California solid waste operations ([2])
- ↑ Hubau, W., Lewis, S. et al 2020: Asynchronous carbon sink saturation in African and Amazonian tropical forests (Nature)
- ↑ FAO, 2008: FAO The State of Food and Agriculture, Part I: Biofuels: Prospects, Risks and Opportunities (FAO)
- ↑ Sandbag, 2019: Playing With Fire: assessment of company plans to burn biomass in EU coal power stations (Sandbag)
- ↑ Carbon Pulse, 2019: EU’s wood-fired power should face carbon price under tougher rules (Carbon Pulse News Agency)
- ↑ Bae, S., Levick, S.R., Heidrich, L. et al. Radar vision in the mapping of forest biodiversity from space. (Nat Commun 10, 4757 (2019) doi:10.1038/s41467-019-12737-x)
- ↑ Almeida D. et al, 2019: Monitoring the structure of forest restoration plantations with a drone-lidar system (International Journal of Applied Earth Observation and Geoinformation)
- ↑ Andrew, R. 2019: Global Carbon Budget 2019 (CICERO Center for International Climate Research)
- ↑ Cockburn, H. 2019: Scientists turn CO2 ‘back into coal’ in breakthrough carbon capture experiment (Independent UK)
- ↑ Rathi, A. 2019: You can now pay to turn your carbon emissions to stone (Quartz Global News)
- ↑ Weston, P. 2019: Scientists create ‘artificial leaf’ that sucks in carbon dioxide and makes fuel (Independent UK)
- ↑ Pierce, R. 2020: Explainer: 10 ways negative emissions could slow climate change (Carbon Brief)